Skip banner
HomeHow Do I?Site MapHelp
Return To Search FormFOCUS
Search Terms: broadband deployment, House or Senate or Joint

Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed

Previous Document Document 98 of 133. Next Document

More Like This
Copyright 1999 Federal News Service, Inc.  
Federal News Service

 View Related Topics 

JUNE 30, 1999, WEDNESDAY

SECTION: IN THE NEWS

LENGTH: 3198 words

HEADLINE: PREPARED TESTIMONY OF
SCOTT C. CLELAND
MANAGING DIRECTOR OF
THE LEGG MASON PRECURSOR GROUP
BEFORE THE HOUSE JUDICIARY COMMITTEE
SUBJECT - HR 1686 "THE INTERNET FREEDOM ACT"
HR 1685 "THE INTERNET GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT ACT OF 1999"

BODY:

TRANSMITTED BY: FEDERAL NEWS SERVICE 620 NATIONAL PRESS BUILDING WASHINGTON, DC
Mr. Chairman, thank you for the honor of testifying before your Committee on "The Internet Freedom Act" and the "Internet Growth and Development Act of 1999."
I am Scott Cleland, Managing Director of the Legg Mason Precursor Group. The views expressed here are mine alone. I request that my full written testimony be printed in its entirety in the hearing record.
By way of introduction, I am not a traditional Wall Street sell-side analyst who analyzes companies or recommends the purchase of stocks. For Legg Mason, I run an investment research group that tracks regulatory, technological, and competitive developments in the communications, technology and e-commerce sectors for large institutional investors. Unlike most of Wall Street, we do not focus on what will happen in the next quarter. We focus on trying to anticipate major investment-relevant change coming in the next three- 18 months.
In that context, I offer the following insights and observations in hopes that they will be useful to the Committee in its deliberations over "The Internet Freedom Act" and the "Internet Growth and Development Act of 1999."
I. Investment and Market Perspective
In general, investors are wary of almost any proposed legislation or regulation because it increases uncertainty -- which investors dislike. However, investors are not much different from the old political adage "where you stand, depends on where you sit." Where investors stand on proposed legislation often depends on what they own in their portfolio. It is important for this Committee to appreciate that its action or inaction on this proposed legislation will have a marginal effect on the overall level of investment, but it could have a large effect on how investment dollars move around within the marketplace.
Market's Perception of Cable: I believe that the market's current very positive outlook for the cable industry rests on three primary assumptions at the heart of the open access debate.
(1) Cable enjoys the best broadband, multiple-service, consumer pipe to the home.
(2) The cable pipe won't be opened up to competition by the government.
(3) Cable will be able to vertically leverage its video market power and customer base into the Internet and e-commerce.
Moreover, the market largely assumes the best case right now about cable's story, that all the new proposed services will pan out in full. The market loves a growth story that faces little competition. In other words, the market views cable's glass as half full.
Market's Perception of Local Telcos: In contrast, I believe the general market perception of the local telcos has been different. Despite the local telcos' positive financial performance since the Telecom Act passed, investor fears of increased competition continue to cloud the local telcos' overall growth outlook. In other words, the market views the local telcos' glass as half empty.
For very different reasons, this Committee's proposed bills cut to the heart of both these industries' growth outlooks and the market's perception of them.
II. The Deregulatory "Trojan Horse": It's All About Preventing Competition. Why has cable closed Internet access and limited streaming video to 10 minutes? Cable's deregulatory rhetoric appears to be a "Trojan Horse" to divert attention from the main event -- reducing the potential for more competition to cable.
A. There's More Than One Threat to the Internet: Both HR1685 and HR 1686 recognize that there is more than one threat to the Internet than just government regulation -- but also anticompetitive behavior by owners of scarce broadband conduit. While it is wise for the Government to let the market work and not regulate, this Committee has also recognized that the market works best when everyone is free to compete and innovate.
Both HR1685 and HR 1686 recognize that one does not have to compromise on competition and nondiscriminatory access to deregulate. The bills offer the Bells data deregulation without compromising the procompetitive principle that the Bells must still provide nondiscriminatory access to their "last-mile" facilities. The Committee's bills take a nonregulatory antitrust approach: "Prohibition of Anticompetitive Behavior or Contracts:" The bills oppose "restraining unreasonably the ability of a service provider from competing."
Who Decided to put Competition in the Backseat? It appears from the tenor of this debate that somehow deregulation and infrastructure deployment are now supposed to be more important public policy goals than promoting competition and protecting consumers. Once again, what congressional action or official FCC ruling reordered these priorities? What decision officially endorsed the trade-off that the "ends" of deregulation and broadband deployment "justify the means" of reducing competition and not safeguarding consumer interests?
B. Deregulatory Misinformation: If one were to listen to much of the current debate, one could get the false impression that the cable industry already was deregulated and that government did not believe cable had market power. In fact, Congress has effectively found that the cable industry has anticompetitively used its scarce conduit control to stifle competition in several markets.
Program Access: In the 1992 Cable Act, Congress found that cable was discriminating anticompetitively against satellite broadcasters, and legislatively obligated cable to provide satellite competitors with nondiscriminatory access and prices to cable programming. That "regulatory" "open access" to cable programming promoted competition and has provided more than 10 million Americans a competitive choice of video distribution supplier in about six years.
Must Carry and Retransmission Consent: The 1992 Cable Act policy was to "ensure that cable television operators do not have undue market power vis-a-vis video programmers and consumers." Congress recognized cable's market power over local TV stations, so Congress gave local TV stations the legal option to either choose "must carry" of their broadcasts or to choose a commercial negotiation through the legal process of retransmission consent.


Leased Access: "To promote competition in the delivery of diverse sources of video programming and to assure that the widest possible diversity of information sources are made available to the public " section 612 of the 1992 Cable Act obligated cable operators to make 10%-15% of their system capacity available for commercial use (resale) because competitors did not have sufficient alternative ways to distribute their product.
Competitive Availability of Navigation Devices: In the 1996 Telecom Act, Congress worried that cable's market power over cable equipment was stifling competition and passed section 629 to "assure the commercial availability to consumers " of cable equipment. Cable can still sell equipment to consumers, but it can not charge a price that is "subsidized" anticompetitively by its cable service. Congress effectively created for consumers an "open access" market for cable equipment. It also created a regulatory sunset of this provision when the FCC finds the market for video programming and video equipment is "fully competitive."
Continuation of an Anticompetitive Pattern? Few are now advocating "deregulating" cable from any of these procompetitive cable obligations described above. Is that because consensus still supports procompetition policies which protect against a widely appreciated pattern of cable anticompetitive behavior? Cable open access is not a new or an isolated problem. It is a continuation of a long and clear pattern of commercial behavior to reduce competition.
Internet access is a new market that largely came into being after passage of the 1996 Telecom Act. Both HR1685 and HR 1686 implicitly recognize that this new form of cable anti-competitive behavior may have to be addressed legislatively again.
III. Why Is Open Access Important?
The issue of cable open access is much more than an industry squabble or a regulatory food fight. In fact, whether the cable plant is open or closed to competitive access is a major fork in the road for this nation's policy towards competition, convergence, the Internet and electronic commerce. Will the nation continue down the open pro- competitive road it has traversed for the last 30 years, or will the nation now divert to a new more closed and potentially anticompetitive road in the future? This is not just about ISPs and "last mile" access. It is even more importantly about vertical linkage of backbone, access, content, and e-commerce.
What's at Stake?
A. Will Internet technology be allowed to compete against cable? By way of analogy, will the government enable Internet competitors to compete against cable with open access as the government enabled Direct Broadcast Satellite (DBS) to compete against cable with program access in 1992?
In all the hype about the Internet and e-commerce, do not forget that about 99% of cable's revenues are still video-related. Cable does not want more programming competition from Internet players. Open access offers a massive increase in consumer video programming choice as technology develops over time (i.e., enabling users to stream video). Instead of having to buy entire packages of programming from cable, Internet competitors could offer micro-programming packages so consumers could buy only the programming they want, when they want it, and how they want it. Most consumers use and want only a fraction of the channels they are forced to buy in a package. If consumers could choose only what they want to see, ultimately no one would have to pay for programming they do not want or support. If consumers wanted to, they could dramatically either decrease or increase their cable bill depending on their individual viewing choices. Almost everywhere else in the economy, the Internet is empowering consumers with more choice. Closed cable access would allow cable video programming to increasingly become an island - impeding outside Internet innovation.
With open access, cable-broadband Internet Service Providers (ISPs) could become a very different industry than their telco-narrowband ISP brethren. Higher speeds could create an entirely new and more competitive video marketplace. Look at how the Internet and e-commerce has flourished because of local telco open access. Broadband Internet competitors on cable probably will be less like today's ISPs, which thrive primarily only on Internet access, e-mail, and customer service, but will also offer competitive programming as Competitive Internet Video Programmers (CIVPs).
B. Will Cable "Corner" the High-End Residential E-Commerce Market? Will conduit control content and e-commerce?
Competition Is an Antidote for Market Power: The government has used the introduction of competition to mitigate the potential for the local telcos to leverage their local market power vertically into adjacent markets.
-- The government opened telephone customer premise equipment to competition, leading to a flourishing competitive market of multiple vendors for interoperable devices that hook up to phone lines.
-- Since the late 1960s, the government has consistently maintained a policy of keeping the regulated communications infrastructure separate from the unregulated computer, data, and now Internet markets -- by ensuring nondiscriminatory access to the network. The result is a flourishing competitive market of more than 6,000 ISPs and tens of thousands of e-commerce companies.
-- The breakup of AT&T and the associated nondiscriminatory access policy has led to robust long distance competition and more than 10 national Internet backbones.
-- The Telecom Act has promoted local competition and nondiscriminatory access, which has led to the creation of dozens of competitive local exchange carriers.
Bambis in the E-commerce Forest? Because there are multiple layers of competition and nondiscriminatory access policies between the local telcos' "last-mile" market power and the Internet, to date, e-commerce companies have not had to worry about a fair unfettered access to their residential customers. In other words, there are tens of thousands of e-commerce "Bambi" companies that currently don't worry about conduit players being able to steer their best customer segment away from them to a cable "preferred" provider. They focus on content, commerce and customers, and assume they will always have access to infrastructure and their customers. Most e-commerce "Bambis" are still naively unaware that there is danger in the e-commerce forest that could lead to the capture of their potential high-end customers by locking these customer into infrastructure and exclusive service before these e-commerce companies ever have a chance to sell to them.
Reducing Competition and Leveraging Market Power: Contrast the nondiscriminatory competitive approach of the telco "last mile" into 98.5 million American homes with cable's discriminatory attempt to reduce competitive access to the nation's other ubiquitous "last mile" into 66 million homes.
Cable's closed access policy enables cable to vertically leverage its market power more freely into e-commerce. Unlike the telecom competition that is designed to limit a local telcos' market power, cable is limiting competition to leverage its market power. For example, cable has contractually established a monopoly distributor of cable Internet access
Home/Road Runner, to ensure no competition from the 6,000 ISPs or the several dozen competitive local carriers. Cable also discriminates by not allowing competitive backbone providers to carry its Internet traffic.
Home/Road Runner also forecloses Internet video programming competition by limiting any streaming video to less than 10 minutes in duration. The absence of competition in cable's intermediary markets combined with ownership of a preferred content and e-commerce portal (i.e., Excite), provides cable the real potential for exercising its market power into the high-end residential e-commerce market.

If cable:
(1) continues to enjoy a dominant share of the residential broadband market (currently cable's broadband market share is 90%+);
(2) can prevent intermediary competition for competitive access; and
(3) can leverage exclusive Internet access with Internet backbone transport to gain a powerful incumbent "default" advantage over competitors;
then cable would be able to substantially lessen competition by effectively limiting their competitors' addressable market. In effect, cable could "corner" a substantial portion of the high-end residential broadband e-commerce market for itself and its "preferred" e-commerce partners.
C. Will Government Keep the Unregulated Internet Separate From Regulated Infrastructure, Which Has Been Key to its Success and Growth to Date? In other words, will the unregulated "virtual" world of the Internet and e-commerce remain separate from the regulated physical infrastructure businesses?
The Internet Is Separate: The Internet is simply a universal communications language that links any type of electronic device over any carrier's physical infrastructure, to deliver any type of information (text, data, graphics, voice or video). In effect, the Internet "delinks" communications from the physical technology. In the past, communications was driven by the physical hardware technology: phone, radio, TV, cable, wireless, or satellite. The Internet is not the physical infrastructure, but the virtual and boundaryless world of communications and e-commerce that rides on top of the various technologies.
Cable Self-Deregulation? Cable is trying to reverse more than 30 years of communications/computer regulatory separation by self-declaring that cable infrastructure and the Internet are one and the same. Cable is trying to "relink" its infrastructure to the Internet in order to cloak itself in the deregulatory rhetoric of the Internet. However, in Congress' much-touted deregulatory Internet policy statement in the Telecom Act, there is no mention of cable or any other infrastructure player. Despite the current confused debate, I can find no place in which Congress or the FCC affirmatively and officially decided that cable was the Internet and, therefore, cable infrastructure should be "unfettered by Federal or state regulation."
D. Schizophrenic Infrastructure Regulation Diverts Convergence. There could not be more of a stark regulatory contrast than the competitive policy the FCC applies to the telcos and to the cable industry. The FCC is polarizing residential broadband investment by hyperregulating the telco monopoly pipe using the broadest regulatory interpretation of the law and taking a laissez-faire approach toward the cable monopoly using the narrowest interpretation of the law. Apparently, the FCC has opposite definitions of competition depending on who is on the receiving end.
-- Current "activist" telecom broadband competition policy is to:
(1) demonopolize by promoting competition on an open, shared network at wholesale prices;
(2) encourage access investment and innovation by Internet competitors; and
(3) prevent the incumbent from anticompetitively cross-subsidizing or leveraging market power vertically.
-- In contrast the current "look the other way and hope" cable broadband policy is the opposite:
(1) it fosters a duopolization by allowing cable a closed proprietary network at retail prices;
(2) it discourages competitive investment and innovation by Internet competitors; and,
(1) it allows the incumbent to cross-subsidize and leverage market power vertically.
Long-Standing Open Access Precedent: Since 1966, the government has had an ongoing regulatory proceeding, Computer Inquiry, whereby it has tried to reconcile the convergence and interdependence of communications transport and enhanced data processing technologies by keeping them separate to the extent possible for regulatory purposes. Neither the 1992 Cable Act, nor the 1996 Telecom Act, nor the World Trade Organization Telecom Agreement specifically anticipated the emergence of cable as a primary broadband data "last-mile" carrier. In the absence of specific legal language, cable has lobbied furiously for political self-deregulation from the long-standing, bipartisan and international consensus supporting the promotion of competition to monopolies and the policy of nondiscriminatory access (i.e., open networks). I can find no vote or official policy decision whereby the government decided to reverse its consensus procompetitive, open network access policy and officially and explicitly decided that the cable "last-mile" should be closed to competition in order to spur deployment.
Mr. Chairman, thank you again for the honor of testifying before your Committee on this important subject.
Attachment: "Too Rosy an Outlook for Residential Broadband Competition?" and accompanying chart: "Precursor Watch: Residential Broadband Deployment Outlook."
END


LOAD-DATE: July 1, 1999




Previous Document Document 98 of 133. Next Document


FOCUS

Search Terms: broadband deployment, House or Senate or Joint
To narrow your search, please enter a word or phrase:
   
About LEXIS-NEXIS® Congressional Universe Terms and Conditions Top of Page
Copyright © 2002, LEXIS-NEXIS®, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.