Skip banner
HomeHow Do I?Site MapHelp
Return To Search FormFOCUS
Search Terms: broadband deployment, House or Senate or Joint

Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed

Previous Document Document 101 of 133. Next Document

More Like This
Copyright 1999 Federal News Service, Inc.  
Federal News Service

 View Related Topics 

JUNE 30, 1999, WEDNESDAY

SECTION: IN THE NEWS

LENGTH: 3091 words

HEADLINE: PREPARED STATEMENT BY
TOD A. JACOBS
SENIOR TELECOMMUNICATIONS ANALYST
SANFORD C. BERNSTEIN & COMPANY
BEFORE THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY
SUBJECT - RE: H.R. 1685 & H.R. 1686

BODY:

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. Thank you for inviting me here today to address the "Internet Freedom Act" and "Internet Growth and Development Act of 1999." My name is Tod Jacobs, and I'm senior telecommunications analyst at Sanford C. Bernstein & Company. Bernstein is an investment management and research firm; one part of the firm manages about $90 billion in equity and fixed income funds. The other side, where I work, advises money managers globally on a number of key industries. My job is to forecast the growth and earnings and stock performance of the telecom industry as well as its largest companies, including the Baby Bells (RBOCs, or regional Bell holding companies), the large long distance carriers and several wireless carriers. Our firm is somewhat unique among brokerage firms in that we do not engage in investment banking; that is, we don't work for any of the companies we cover as analysts. We therefore avoid conflicts of interest, and have the ability to speak our minds without fear of repercussion. My only clients are the analysts and portfolio managers charged with investing in telecom stocks. I am neither a lawyer nor regulatory expert nor engineer, but rather deal with all issues relevant to telecom investing. My only mandate is to be right. And for the record, I'm currently favoring long distance companies such as WorldCom, Sprint and AT&T, and have neutral ratings on the RBOCs. And indeed, I was quite bullish on the RBOCs from early 1997 through June of 1998, when AT&T announced its acquisition of TCI - a transaction that brought with it for the first time the specter of facilities-based local residential competition to the RBOCs. Also for the record, my colleague Tom Wolzien, who covers video media and online, currently has buy ratings on AOL and MediaOne, and neutral ratings on Time Warner and Cox.
The bills before you have, in my opinion, been defined through three primary goals:
First, to unfetter the RBOCs relative to certain obligations they bear to provide discounted resale and unbundled access to their networks to competitors. Second, to fetter the cable companies with obligations that are quite similar to those that would be at the same time lifted from the shoulders of the RBOCs. Third, to loosen certain business- line restrictions shouldered by the RBOCs in relation to the transport of data services across LATA boundaries.
It's my intention to focus on the issue of open access to cable high- speed transport services, and then to touch on the issue of allowing the RBOCs into inter-LATA data services prior to letting them into inter-LATA, or long-distance, voice.
In many ways the problem with discussing these issues is that it's easy to lose sight of the big picture. We get lost in endless legal and technical discussions about the propriety of one set of rules versus another; and special interests tend to create one-sided distortions of the underlying reality. In my opinion, all these issues revolve around one basic question: what is the path toward competition - both with respect to telecom services and broadband services? And why and how are the two related?
Fortunately, we have something of a blueprint of the competitive goal - a fuzzy and at times contradictory one - but a blueprint nonetheless: namely, the Telecom Act of 1996. Despite endless wrangling around its details and implementation, if you had your 9- year old read it, once he woke up he'd tell you that there's a simple goal: the RBOCs need to open up the local exchange to competition. And in return, they'll be let into long distance. The truth is that any of us could this afternoon go and start a long-distance business from scratch in our garage that could easily serve residential and small business customers. It's local that's hard. And that's why the Act of 1996 was about opening local markets. And it appears that Congress believed that the RBOCs would not be properly incented to open up local if they first received approval to offer long distance.
Where are we in pursuing that goal? Not very far - it seems. In Exhibit 1, we present the RBOC lines lost to resale and unbundling as of the most recent quarter. Three years and one month after passage of the act, the highest market share losers so far are BellSouth and US West, with about 2.7% each lost to resale and unbundling, followed by SBC with 2.6%, Ameritech with 2.4% and Bell Atlantic with 1.9%. Not very impressive. What's more, if you cut more finely, you'll find that business line losses are in the 3-4% range, but that residential share loss is holding at about 1%. And while these numbers don't include loss to carriers serving customers on their own facilities, since the RBOCs can't or won't break out the data, we strongly believe that at best you're talking about an incremental 2-4 points of share loss. And at least 95% of that relates to business customers, again leaving residential to about 1%.
Why? First, because while business lines represent only about 35% of total access lines, they nonetheless drive about three quarters of RBOC profit due to the industry's strange and artificial pricing structure. Residential lines are nearly profitless, and are geographically dispersed, while subsidy-laden business lines are extremely rich, and are geographically clustered in small areas. So no one approaching the industry fresh as a competitor would ever try to attack the residential market, especially if it required the deployment of expensive facilities. Second, as we'll see, with the exception of AT&T, no single long distance company has sufficient consumer exposure, and therefore sufficient fear, to make the expensive investments necessary to enter residential on a large scale.
Now, the reality is that the initial market-opening strategy pushed by the FCC in 1996 and 1997- a highly discounted form of resale known as rebundling, or the unbundled network element platform (UNE-P) -- would have drawn all of the LD companies into residential since it offered about a 35% average discount, which most could have at least broken even on. That's worth doing if the bundling in of a local service product serves to hang onto profitable long distance customers longer. But the RBOCs believed that even long distance entry wasn't worth the price of UNE-P. So they decided not to pursue it - and indeed had it overturned by the Eighth Circuit in mid-1997. And even though it would cost them long-distance entry, the RBOCs were content to grow earnings in double digits based upon the strength of the local markets. At the same time, numerous strategies were employed to skirt the 271 entry process: the Qwest joint-marketing deals with US West and Ameritech, and the famous "Bill of Attainder" arguments put forth in two circuits that attempted to have the inter-LATA restrictions declared unconstitutional.
For their parts, bereft of UNE-P, each of the major long-distance companies attempted to offer plain vanilla resale of local residential service - at about a third the effective discount of UNE-P - but quickly found that you couldn't lose a bit on the margin and make it up in the volume. So they stopped trying, and the industry entered a two-year truce, particularly with respect to residential.
The one with the problem, though, was AT&T. That is, the company knew well that eventually the RBOCs would enter long distance. When they did, they would easily add a long distance component to the existing local service. And AT&T, with its $23 billion consumer long distance business - unable to offer a bundle that included local service - would simply get crushed.

That simple and sad reality led the company to purchase TCI - a strategy that caused the company to invest $40 billion and to dilute its earnings severely - in the process crushing the stock for several months - all in pursuit of a path into the home for local service.
Make no mistake about it. AT&T didn't buy TCI because it liked the cable business. It bought TCI for defensive reasons, for fear of getting crushed in consumer long distance by the RBOCs if it couldn't offer a bundle that included local service. Second, because AT&T is a national company and TCI is regional, AT&T couldn't stop with TCI. Thus, the company went about pursuing joint ventures with other cable companies in order to get access to enough homes to make a difference. But those deals were hard to come by, with only Time Warner coming close among large cable companies. And that's despite AT&T's willingness to pay upfront fees for access, and to foot nearly all of the capital expenditures - about $500 per subscribing home on average over the next 5 years, or somewhere between $9 billion and $12 billion, not including the cost of upgrading TCI's lines to support two-way digital services (another $2-3 billion) to roll out on a nationwide basis.
Moreover, it was the difficulty in clinching cable resale deals that forced the company to again dilute its earnings, this time spending $60 billion, to acquire MediaOne, which despite its relatively small footprint, nonetheless holds the key to cementing the national footprint, since it will ultimately lead to resale deals with Comcast and a finalization of the Time Warner deal. Taken in sum, the creation of this strategy is plainly and simply the first fruit of the Act of 1996 - the only large-scale strategy being pursued by any telecom company that will bring residential competition to the local exchange.
What has this to do with open access to broadband cable? Everything. Because when you spend an average of $3,300-3,400 a subscriber to acquire cable companies, then add $150 a home passed to enable two-way services, then spend $500 a subscriber for those that take local telephone service, you've got to get a return on your capital. And the combination of basic cable and local telephone won't come close to driving that return. Only the inclusion of incremental growth services like high-speed data give you a prayer. And according to several leading analysts, even that won't be enough. So the fate of broadband services is critical. And to the extent that AT&T's ability to drive an adequate return on broadband services is threatened by the unknown economics that regulators and legislators could mandate in open cable access, Wall Street will deny AT&T and all other cable companies the capital to build the broadband pipe. I would be the first to downgrade my buy recommendation on AT&T through the creation of that uncertainty.
How do we respond to the concerns of the major players?
Argument: AOL could be denied access at will to the cable plant.
Let's note a few facts:
The company currently has 16 million online customers versus under 800,000 at the cable companies in total; so clearly it will be some time before the company is marginalized by the activities of cable.
AOL has already struck resale deals for broadband xDSL access on a commercial basis, including volume discounts, with Bell Atlantic and SBC. We believe that more RBOC deals are in the works. So the company will have broadband access to tens of millions of homes over the next 12 months. That's not to mention commercial deals struck with satellite.
AOL's service is a proprietary one. Customers of other Internet Service Providers (ISPs) are denied access to AOL's content; in addition the company appears to be opposed to any attempt to regulate the internet - except as regards open access to cable plant. So there is an issue of consistency.
We believe that AOL can and should pursue commercial deals with cable, and that such deals could be extremely beneficial to both sides.
Finally, any one of the ISPs, including AOL, could elect to invest capital and gain local franchise approval to overbuild the existing cable plants, just as Ameritech has done in parts of Chicago and Detroit and a number of municipalities have done elsewhere in the country.
Argument: the RBOCs are being treated unfairly since they have to unbundle and resell their plant while cable is not yet subject to similar obligations.
There is an inequity in the regulation of the two industries. But we would argue that the long-term solution to the problem is the eventual deregulation of the RBOCs in the high-speed data area, not regulation of the fledgling cable high-speed industry.
Several other key points:
DSL Deployment Depends on Cable Modem Deployment: It is precisely the AT&T national cable-telephony strategy, along with the general aggressive investment posture of the other cable companies with respect to high-speed data deployment that has driven the RBOCs to begin to aggressively deploy xDSL. Indeed that technology has been around for several years and the RBOCs have been very slow to deploy it until recently, especially since it represents the threat of cannibalization of the RBOC's $5 billion private line business, which offers similar speed services for a fraction of the price.
RBOC Push Toward Ubiquity Depends on Cable Modem Deployment: Only 40- 50% of RBOC access lines are currently addressable with xDSL given line lengths and the presence of certain splicing and multiplexing technologies on many access lines that preclude xDSL deployment. To address this problem, the RBOCs will have to spend $8-12 billion over the next several years to push fiber further down into the neighborhood to enable ubiquitous xDSL deployment. Such investments are only now being announced, and are clearly driven by the desire not to lose the market to cable modems. In the absence of a cable modem threat, these incremental investments are unlikely to be made, certainly not on the accelerated basis now being contemplated. Moreover, more aggressive RBOC spending will be met with further cable investment. Few things will prove better for the consumer than a battle to bring broadband to the home.
AT&T & Cable Open to Negotiations: AT&T and other cable companies have made clear that they are open to commercial relationships with ISPs such as AOL. Indeed they'd be crazy not to strike deals, and Wall Street is pushing them to do so quickly, if only to end the reign of that killer of stocks called "regulatory risk" - but more so because it's good business to have as many people selling your services as possible if the terms are reasonable. A vibrant commercial resale market would obviate the need for regulated unbundling.
Why Regulate a Fledgling Industry Now When You Can Do it Later? The real fear is that cable behaves with respect to broadband services the way it did in programming (where anti-competitive behavior led to regulation in the early 1990s). The FCC policy has been to say: "We'll leave you alone for now ut we're watching." This shot across the bow has, in our view, been noted by cable managements. We recognize, however, the need of the FCC to be assured that the technical systems being established today will not practically preclude regulation to counter any actual anti-competitive abuses should they occur years from now. It is in the province of the FCC to be certain that the design of the billions of dollars of hardware and systems being installed by cable now allow for the consideration of regulation of high speed data at the system level in the future if anti-competitive abuses occur. I know my colleague Tom Wolzien will be discussing this issue in his comments at the FCC on July 8th.
At the end of the day, the question comes down to one of a policy choice. In our opinion, the first goal of the Telecom Act is local - and especially residential local - competition. Without an ability to buttress with incremental broadband services the huge expenditures required (mostly of AT&T) to roll out competitive local telephone service, local telecom competition won't ever come. In turn, the presence of a vibrant cable investment posture in broadband services depends upon the perceived ability to generate returns on capital. To the extent that those returns could be curtailed by regulation, cable won't build. To the extent that the cable build is slowed or stopped, the RBOCs will slow their finally-accelerating broadband deployment - that's the rational thing to do. No one wants to deploy capital for the sake of being popular, especially when it dilutes earnings or risks cannibalization of other services. So in many ways, the choice is between two major broadband buildouts in competition (in addition to several niche competing access technologies like MMDS, LMDS and DBS and standard wireless) or no major broadband buildout. And with it, no local telephone competition.
Finally, on the subject of RBOC inter-LATA relief with respect to data services:
Again, the question is one of policy goals. For the past 2-1/2 years the RBOCs were mostly content to sit out long distance entry as long as local wasn't threatened. All that changed with the new AT&T cable- telephony strategy, which holds the possibility that AT&T could reach the consumer with a bundled offering (local, long distance, data and video) before the RBOC does. Now, numerous RBOCs have decided that UNE-P might be worth the price of admission to long distance after all.
What's the risk of allowing for an easing of the restriction on data? It depends on what you think is driving the RBOCs toward market opening. In our opinion, over the next 5 years, 60% of the growth in telecom services revenue will be driven by local and long distance data and Internet products. Local and long distance voice products, on the other hand, will drive only about 15% of growth, despite making up two-thirds of the total telecom pie (Exhibit 2).
More to the point, focusing on inter-LATA services only (including long-distance voice, long-distance data and internet services - which RBOCs are precluded from offering), about 85% of all inter-LATA growth over the next five years is expected to come from data and internet products. Only 15% is expected to come from long-distance voice (Exhibit 3). Thus it should be rather clear that data is the key to inter-LATA growth in the future.
So the question is rather simple: if the RBOCs are allowed into inter- LATA data, thus gaining access to 85% of all inter-LATA growth even without access to traditional long distance voice - are they likely to be proactive in opening up the $90 billion local market in order to gain access to the other 15% of the growth? The answer to this question should help you determine the proper course of action toward achieving your policy goals.
END


LOAD-DATE: July 1, 1999




Previous Document Document 101 of 133. Next Document


FOCUS

Search Terms: broadband deployment, House or Senate or Joint
To narrow your search, please enter a word or phrase:
   
About LEXIS-NEXIS® Congressional Universe Terms and Conditions Top of Page
Copyright © 2002, LEXIS-NEXIS®, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.