Skip banner
HomeHow Do I?Site MapHelp
Return To Search FormFOCUS
Search Terms: estate w/10 tax w/10 repeal, House or Senate or Joint

Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed

Previous Document Document 21 of 54. Next Document

More Like This
Copyright 2000 eMediaMillWorks, Inc. 
(f/k/a Federal Document Clearing House, Inc.)  
Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony

April 11, 2000, Tuesday

SECTION: CAPITOL HILL HEARING TESTIMONY

LENGTH: 7880 words

HEADLINE: TESTIMONY April 11, 2000 JOSEPH M. KAHN HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS TAX OVERHAUL PROPOSALS

BODY:
Statement of Joseph M. Kahn House Ways and Means Committee Hearings on Tax Reform April 11 - 13, 2000 Thank you for the opportunity to contribute to these hearings on replacing the income tax. I am providing this statement on behalf of the Stanford University Decisions and Ethics Center. From 1996 to 1997, I had the privilege of coordinating a team of economic researchers within the Decisions and Ethics Center analyzing the impact on households of a change from the current income tax regime to the National Retail Sales Tax (NRST) proposed by the group Americans for Fair Taxation. This proposal is now embodied in H.R. 2525. Herein, I present the main findings of our study. The study was based on the 1996 income tax code, and assumed that the tax regime change would take place in 1998. Though the income tax code continues to change each year and the proposed date of changeover to the NRST remains in the future, I would not expect any major changes in the study's general conclusions. 1. Summary of Main Findings The Decisions and Ethics Center at Stanford University investigated the impact on households of a change from the current tax regime to the national retail sales tax (NRST) proposed by Americans for Fair Taxation. Under this proposal, all federal income and payroll taxes would be repealed, federal revenues would be replaced by the NRST at a (tax-inclusive) rate of 23%, and all families would be granted a rebate for the amount of taxes paid at the federal poverty line. Our study focused on individual families over their remaining lifetimes rather than statistical aggregates in a single year, Our analysis yielded several major conclusions regarding the impact on families of a change to the NRST tax regime. The current tax code is complex and there is probably no change which can guarantee that everyone would be better off. However, we find that most families would enjoy higher real lifetime consumption under the NRST than under the current regime. This is due to several factors, including lower tax burdens on many households, lower compliance costs, lower marginal tax rates, and increased economic growth and efficiency. Some wealthier seniors may experience a reduction in purchasing power under the NRST. However, their own financial well-being may not be the only issue they consider in their decision to support a particular tax regime. Other factors, such as the effect on their grandchildren or on the poor, may take precedence in their decision. This statement highlights the following points: - Incentives to work and to save tend to be higher under the new regime-over 20% higher for many households. This is primarily due to the replacement of high marginal income tax rates with a flat rate on consumption. - Middle-class families tend to be financially better off under the change. A combination of factors including lower compliance costs, lower marginal tax rates, and increased economic growth and efficiency contribute to improve their prospects. - Existing homeowners tend to benefit under the change, despite the removal of the mortgage interest deduction. This is because existing owner-occupied homes would increase in value, while existing mortgages would become more affordable. - Low-income families tend to be significantly better off financially under the change. They would effectively pay none of the national sales tax under the change because they would receive rebates which cover the amount of taxes paid at poverty level. In addition, any federal benefits they receive would be indexed to match possible increases in after-tax consumer prices. - Younger households tend to be financially better off after the change, benefiting from improved economic conditions over their entire careers. - Middle- and lower-income seniors tend to do better financially under the change. Social security payments would be indexed to a tax-inclusive price index, holding recipients harmless against any changes in after- tax prices. Additionally, the NRST rebate would more than make up for any losses in after-tax purchasing power of pension benefits for these seniors. - Some wealthier seniors would tend not to benefit from the redistribution of the tax burden. This is because wealthier seniors have a larger portion of financial assets whose after-tax purchasing power may decline under the new regime. However, for many seniors the removal of income taxes from asset earnings and retirement account disbursements, the exclusion of their existing homes from the NRST, and the repeal of the estate tax would more than make up for any initial loss in asset values. - Considered over a lifetime, the progressivity of the NRST would be similar to that of the current income tax regime. The progressivity of the NRST would be achieved through use of a rebate and replacement of regressive payroll taxes. 2. Study Methodology Our goal was to translate the economic effects of a change in the tax regime into understandable impacts on individual households. Traditional methodologies, which examine statistical averages for a single year and aggregate very different households, lack vital data and often do not reveal important and key information. In our analysis, we focus on specific households, considering the impact of the actual tax code. Further, we examined households over their entire remaining lifetime rather than focusing on a single year. Examining a variety of family profiles, we develop critical insights into the effects of a change in the tax regime. We then varied individual household characteristics and economic assumptions to ensure that our conclusions are robust. Taxes affect the household either directly, or indirectly through the economy (see Figure I below). Direct taxation on the household includes individual income taxes'(including the earned income tax credit), propert7y taxes, and the employee portion of payroll taxes. Indirect taxes are collected from businesses (including corporate income taxes, the employer portion of the payroll tax, sales and service taxes, excise taxes, and corporate property taxes). Businesses serve as intermediaries between workers, investors, and consumers. So all indirect taxes and other costs on business are ultimately paid by households: through reduced wages and benefits, lower investment returns, and higher prices. Economists cannot agree about how the indirect tax burden is allocated among these three economic activities. However, it is certain that all indirect taxes and other costs are ultimately paid by households. Figure 1. All Taxes Fall on Households Figure 1 found on hardcopy In addition to the visible tax revenues collected by government, there are several effects of taxation which are hidden, or less visible. These include seigniorage (the inflation tax), compliance burden of the tax code, economic distortions, and slower economic growth. Our method accounted for the combination of direct, indirect, and hidden taxation in an integrated framework. Differences in direct taxes were computed by applying the tax code to a household's financial situation, directly affecting the finds available for investment and consumption. Changes in indirect and hidden taxes were distributed to household economic activities of work, investment, and consumption. The taxes' magnitude and incidence result in changes to the after-tax market prices, wages and investment returns available to the household. Resulting changes in the household's annual finances lead to different levels of real consumption and investment, which carry through to affect the household's finances over its remaining lifetime. These changes are then integrated to produce a summary measure of the effect on a household's remaining real lifetime consumption. 3. Economic Assumptions We compared the effects on real lifetime consumption of replacing the 1996 Federal Income Tax code with the National Retail Sales Tax proposed by Americans for Fair Taxation (AFT). Throughout, we attempt to match AFT's proposed tax rate of 23% (tax-inclusive) * on all final goods and services, to exclude from taxation any resale of existing consumer-owned housing, and to include a rebate to all families based on federal poverty levels for a given family size. We have also followed AFT's proposal that Social Security is indexed to a consumer price index which includes the NRST. We should note that we analyzed only law-abiding households, those attempting to comply with the actual tax code. Our conclusions would not remain valid for households engaged in criminal enterprises, or otherwise able to evade their current income taxes. Our base case economic assumptions include a 3% inflation rate under the status quo (with nominal tax brackets indexed for inflation), incidence of direct taxes entirely on the household, employer payroll taxes incident on workers, corporate income taxes incident on investors, an NRST distributed two-thirds to consumers and one-third to factors of production (divided between workers and investors by their value share in the economy), a 2% increase in economic efficiency (real purchasing power) from lower compliance costs (i.e., significantly less resources used to deal with filing complex income tax forms), a 1% increase in economic efficiency from other economic effects such as lower marginal tax rates, and a minor 0.05% increase in real wage growth under the NRST due to effects such as increased investment. We tested variations in these base case assumptions to ensure the robustness of our results. We found that perhaps the most significant change in the level of improvement for many families is if the replacement tax rate is changed. Replacing the current income tax with a consumption tax, one might expect at least the modest macro-economic improvements mentioned above at any revenue- neutral tax rate. However, at the time of this analysis there was some uncertainty as to the rate. A lower or higher tax rate would obviously lead to either a better or a more modest improvement (respectively) in most families' real life-time consumption than is calculated at 23%. For low-income families, any differences from the base case results tend to be small, as a proportionately-changed rebate makes up for-any change in -the NRST tax over the bulk of their expenditures. Differences would be more marked for middle and higher-income families, though the shape of graphs and general conclusions that we present would remain valid over a range of possible rates. - A tax-inclusive rate is used for easier comparison with the current income tax rates, which are for gross (tax- inclusive) income. A 23% tax rate on gross sales corresponds to a 30% tax rate on net sales. The middle federal income tax bracket in 1996 was 3 1 % of gross income, corresponding to a 45% tax rate on net income. 4. Effects on Typical Households We began our study with an analysis of the finances of a typical middle-class family-the "Cleavers." The Cleavers are a married couple, aged 40. They own their home and are struggling to meet their mortgage payments while raising their two children (ages 10 and 11). Both parents are employed outside of the home. Some key financial information about the Cleavers is shown in Table I (below). Table 1 found on hardcopy In Figure 2 (below), we find that families with the Cleavers' household profile would be financially better off under the NRST regime. Even over a wide range of incomes - from poverty level, about $16,000 per year for the Cleavers' family of four, to the higher income levels families with this profile would be better off than under the current income tax regime. A combination of factors including lower tax burdens, lower compliance costs, lower marginal tax rates, and increased economic growth and efficiency would allow middle-class families like the Cleavers to enjoy higher real lifetime consumption under the NRST than under the federal income tax. Effect on Homeowners One issue of concern to many middle-class households is the effect of the change on the value of their homes. Because the sales tax would apply only to new homes, the market value of owner-occupied homes would increase under the new tax regime (to the point where newly constructed homes would not be disadvantaged from the viewpoint of prospective home buyers). Also, homeowners with fixed-rate mortgages would find it easier to make their mortgage payments under the NRST regime. This is because if enough of the NRST falls on consumers, after-tax consumer prices would rise to some "tent. So mortgages could be paid off with less valuable dollars. Figure 2. Lifetime Improvement under NRST for the Cleavers* Figure 2 found on hardcopy It is also possible that mortgage interest rates would decline, which would further benefit existing and prospective homeowners (though this effect is not included in our base case analysis). Since many middle-aged families already own their homes and tend to have substantial outstanding fixed-rate mortgages, they would be relatively better off under the NRST regime. Figure 2 (above) illustrates the relative improvement of current homeowners. 5. Variations with Income Low-income Households A critical factor in examining low-income households is the status and amount of government subsidies (including transfer payments) that they receive. These include Supplemental Security Income and food stamps. The working poor not receiving government subsidies tend to be better off under the NRST regime. This enhancement of their financial condition is due to the rebate system, which effectively exempts the working poor from paying any of the NRST. The repeal of the payroll tax allows this group to take home their entire paycheck and avoid the substantial payroll taxes (less earned income tax credit) that they face under the current federal tax system. They are also relieved of the indirect effects of replaced corporate income and payroll taxes that currently decrease their wages and increase the prices they pay as consumers. Figure 3 (below) illustrates the improvement that would be experienced by low-income families with other characteristics similar to those of the Cleavers. Chart found on hardcopy Cleavers' household career average gross wages (in 1996 dollars) Figure 3. Lifetime Improvement under NRST for Low-Income Cleavers Figure 3 found on hardcopy Currently, most government transfer payments (such as food stamps, Supplementary Security Income, and Medicaid) are indexed for inflation. It is possible that these transfer payments would be indexed to an after-tax consumer price indicator (CPI) that includes the NRST. If so, families would receive both indexed transfer payments and the NRST rebate. Figure 4 (below) illustrates the improvement under the NRST for the "Lowes", a low-income family with four children. The Lowe household receives enough government subsidies each year to bring them to 100% of poverty line consumption (about $22,000 annually for the Lowe family of six). A combination of rebate and full indexing of benefits would lead to substantial financial improvement for low-income families like the Lowes. In effect, indexing benefits to a CPI that includes the NRST would over-compensate for the change, as the rebate alone already reimburses the entire tax. Even if their subsidies were indexed to a CPI that ofily partially or not at all included the national retail sales tax, the rebate effectively exempts these families from the NRST, ensuring that they would still be roughly even or financially better off. Under welfare reform that occurred after this study took place, we expect that those families with household gross wages averaging in the lowest range of figure 4 over their entire remaining careers would be unusual cases. Figure 4. Lifetime Improvement under NRST for a Low-Income Family Receiving Government Subsidies Figure 4 found on hardcopy High-income Households Working households with higher incomes would no longer be subject to progressively higher marginal income tax rates, and tend to improve under the NRST regime. The top end of the Cleavers' graph in Figure 2 illustrates their improvement. 6. Variations with Age We found that age is an important factor in determining the effect of the NRST on households. Young Households Younger households, as illustrated by the "Juniors", tend to be financially better off after the change. The Juniors are a married couple, aged 25. They both work, and hope to buy a home and start a family someday. They are just now beginning their careers, and would experience most of their working lives under the new regime. A combination of factors including lower compliance costs, lower marginal tax rates, and increased economic growth and efficiency would allow younger families like the Juniors to enjoy higher real lifetime consumption under the NRST than under the federal income and payroll tax regime. Figure 5 (below) illustrates the improvement in lifetime consumption for the Juniors over a wide range of income levels. Juniors' household career average gross wages (1 996 dollars) Figure 5. Lifetime Improvement under NRST for a Young Family Figure 5 found on hardcopy Elderly Households The "Seniors" represent at The Seniors represent a typical retired couple. We find that the impact of the NRST depends critically on the amount and composition of their savings. Because the sales tax applies only to new homes, the value of the elderly's home equity tends to increase under the new tax regime. Also, portfolios with a higher proportion of their wealth in tax-deferred status (such as in IRAs and "401(k)" plans) and in unrealized capital gains would do relatively better under the NRST, since these holdings would no longer be subject to federal income tax. Some wealthier seniors would tend not to benefit from the redistribution of the tax burden. This is because wealthier seniors have a larger portion of financial assets whose after-tax purchasing power may decline under the new regime. However, for many seniors the removal of income taxes on asset earnings and retirement account disbursements, and the exclusion of their existing homes from the NRST, along with the repeal of the estate tax more than make up for any initial loss in asset values. Most elderly couples with moderate or limited financial resources would be significantly better off under the NRST (see figure 6). The rebate in place would already cover all taxes on essentials (including some formerly hidden- taxes built-in to today's prices). Provisions to fully index Social Security for any increase in after-tax consumer prices would then more than compensate for any loss on these families' modest savings. And for those households with estates over $1,200,000, the removal of estate taxes could more than make up for any loss of the estate's purchasing power. Figure 6 shows these effects on the Seniors for a wide range of net worth (including home equity and private pension funds). As a point of reference for this figure, the median family net worth for a household whose head was between 65 and 74 years of age in 1992 was listed as $103,600 (Federal Reserve Bulletin , October 1994). This suggests that the majority of seniors are described in the lower range of wealth in figure 6, and would experience considerable improvement under the NRST. Seniors' net worth (in thousands of 1996 dollars) Figure 6. Lifetime Effect of NRST for the Seniors under a Range of Financial Profiles at Retirement Figure 6 found on hardcopy While some wealthier Seniors may experience a reduction in purchasing power, their own financial well-being might not be the only issue they consider in their decision to support a particular tax regime. Factors such as the effect on their grandchildren or on the poor may take precedence in their decision. 7. Effects on Marginal Tax Rates Under the NRST regime, marginal tax rates on work and savings would be substantially lower for many households, increasing their incentives to work and save. This is primarily due to the replacement of high marginal income tax rates with a low flat rate on consumption. We measured the incentives to work, computing the additional (after-tax) real goods and services that a household could consume by working additional hours. For example, suppose that the Cleavers are contemplating working an extra hour a year for each year over the course of their remaining careers. And suppose that after all taxes under the existing tax regime, they could purchase a total of 4 pairs of shoes with their additional pay. If, under the NRST, they could instead purchase 5 pairs of shoes for that same extra work, then their marginal incentives will have increased by 25%. Figure 7 (below) shows that although the marginal incentives may decrease for some low-income households, a broad range of households experience significantly increased incentives. Incentives to work rise by over 20% for many families, depending on their earnings. On an economy- wide level, these improved incentives would lead to higher economic growth and efficiency. Cleavers' household career average gross wages(inl996dollars) Figure 7. Effect on Cleavers' Marginal Incentives to Work Figure 7 found on hardcopy 8. Regressivity Analysis There is a common perception that consumption taxes are regressive, which would be supported in a myopic single-year analysis of the tax system. The argument is that: In a given year wealthy people save a higher fraction of their income than poor people, so the wealthy would pay a lower fraction of their income in consumption taxes. However, a lifetime analysis reveals that most or all of the saved income of a household is eventually consumed in retirement or by the heirs, at which time it is subject to the consumption tax. So over a lifetime, a consumption tax-without a rebate-is roughly flat across income categories. Under the NRST, a consumption tax is combined with a rebate which refunds all taxes up to poverty-level consumption. This clearly makes the NRST a progressive tax. 9. Conclusions Because the combination of the current tax code and government subsidies is extremely complex, there is probably no change that can guarantee everyone to be better off. But under the National Retail Sales Tax proposed by Americans for Fair Taxation, several factors would allow most families to enjoy higher real lifetime consumption than under the current federal income and payroll tax regime. These factors include: - a rebate which would keep the amount of taxes paid by most households similar to or lower than the current income tax regime, and would effectively exempt low- income households from the NRST, - indexing of Social Security, which would effectively hold recipients harmless against possible after-tax price increases, - lower compliance costs, - lower marginal tax rates, and - increased economic growth and efficiency Some wealthier seniors would tend not to benefit from the redistribution of the tax burden. However, their own financial well-being might not be the only issue that wealthier seniors consider in their decision to support a particular tax regime. Other factors, such as the effect on their grandchildren or on the poor, may take precedence in their decision. I would like to again thank the committee for-the opportunity to contribute this testimony., Additionally, I should like to recognize a number of individuals that were helpful in this effort. This research has benefited from discussions with William W. Beach, Dale W. Jorgenson, James M. Poterba, and Gary Robbins. David R. Burton and Laura D. Dale have contributed a number of questions and valuable discussions. I am grateful for the dedicated assistance of Roberto Szechtrnan and Ellynne T. Dec, along with Decisions and Ethics Center research assistants J. Eric Bickel, William F. Carone, Alexis G. Collomb, Jeffrey D. Cornwell, George K. Ferguson, Kenneth B. Malpass, and Marcia F. Tsugawa. Our lifetime model and methodology are an extension of work by Stephen M. Malinak, Frederick V. Giarrusso, and Jeffrey K. Belkora, along with suggested improvements from Paul B. Skov, James M. Knappenberger, Derek D. Ayers, and Michael M. Reeds. Special thanks to Elizabeth C. Brierly for editing large portions of this report. Research guidance was provided by Frederick V. Giarrusso and Center Director Ronald A. Howard. The Decisions and Ethics Center gratefully acknowledges help from those volunteers, and a gift from the National Tax Research Committee that enabled this research effort. Sincerely, Joseph M. Kahn

LOAD-DATE: April 18, 2000, Tuesday




Previous Document Document 21 of 54. Next Document


FOCUS

Search Terms: estate w/10 tax w/10 repeal, House or Senate or Joint
To narrow your search, please enter a word or phrase:
   
About LEXIS-NEXIS® Congressional Universe Terms and Conditions Top of Page
Copyright © 2001, LEXIS-NEXIS®, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.