Skip banner
HomeHow Do I?Site MapHelp
Return To Search FormFOCUS
Search Terms: United Airlines AND U.S. Airways AND Merger, House or Senate or Joint

Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed

Previous Document Document 48 of 110. Next Document

More Like This
Copyright 2000 eMediaMillWorks, Inc. 
(f/k/a Federal Document Clearing House, Inc.)  
Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony

June 21, 2000, Wednesday

SECTION: CAPITOL HILL HEARING TESTIMONY

LENGTH: 4774 words

HEADLINE: TESTIMONY June 21, 2000 ALBERT A FOER PRESIDENT AMERICAN ANTITRUST INSTITUTE SENATE COMMERCE, SCIENCE AND TRANSPORTATION UNITED ARLINES - US AIRWAY MERGER

BODY:
JUNE 21, 2000 TESTIMONY OF ALBERT A. FOER ON BEHALF OF THE AMERICAN ANTITRUST INSTITUTE Concerning Airline Mergers BEFORE THE COMMERCE, SCIENCE AND TRANSPORTATION COMMITTEE UNITED STATES SENA'TE Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: Thank you for this opportunity to present this statement on behalf of the American Antitrust Institute regarding the proposed acquisition of USAirways by United Airlines. I am Albert A. Foer, President of the American Antitrust Institute. The American Antitrust Institute is an independent non-profit education, research and advocacy organization described on the Internet at www.antitrustinstitute.org . We are generally centrist and pro- competition in orientation and operate with the assistance of an advisory board composed of many of the leaders of the antitrust community, including academicians and practitioners in the fields of law, economics, and business. It is always difficult for an outsider to comment on the impact of a particular proposed merger. The Department of Justice Antitrust Division, investigating whether the proposed- acquisition of USAirways by United Airlines violates Section 7 of the Clayton Act, will have the advantage of proprietary information, strategic planning documents, commentary of competitors and industry experts, and detailed economic analysis to which we are not privy. Nevertheless, a transaction of this size, creating a single airline with over one-quarter of the national market and a dramatically larger share for many city pairs, naturally raises a variety of questions for consumers of air transportation. Our statement will focus on three questions: How well is airline competition working currently? What effect will this merger have on competition and consumers? -And is there a viable remedy short of blocking the merger? 1. How well is airline competition working currently? The deregulation of air transportation that has occurred since 1978 has had mixed results. On the one hand, prices are relatively low for many routes and consumers are flying far more than they were in 1978. These are substantial benefits. On the other hand, for city pairs where there is little, if any, competition, rates are inordinately high. Consumers often report that they do not feel very sovereign in their experiences with air travel, criticizing both price and service components. With respect to prices, the airlines have mastered the art of price discrimination, in an attempt to charge each customer the highest price that customer is willing to pay for a reservation. (Ironically, this price is called, in economics, the consumer's "reservation price".) Price discrimination on is only possible where there is market power and the extraordinary role that price discrimination plays in air transportation reflects that the airlines do generally have a high degree of market power. Where does this market power come from? At first glance, the industry appears to be structured in a reasonably competitive way. On a national level, there are three dominant airlines of approximate parity (United, American, and Delta) but there are three additional major players, USAirways, Northwestern, and Continental, which bring real competition to certain regions and routes. (Northwestern and Continental are in the process of merging but have been challenged by the Antitrust Division.) In addition, Southwest has a significant impact as the low price maverick in those markets where it has a presence, and a modest number of small carriers also provide the consumer with a degree of choice on some routes. But one must also look at several other factors, which work to reduce the intensity of rivalry. These include: (1)A system of alliances that enhances the seamlessness of travel for many consumers but also undermines the degree of competitive threat that an airline represents in regard to its allies. Alliances can be viewed as partial mergers, and in that view we already have only three truly separate national air systems. The collaborative nature of the industry implies that there is less vigorous rivalry than meets the eye. (2)A hub-and-spoke system facilitates more frequent flights and more efficient use of equipment, but in conjunction with strategic practices that deter entry, has resulted in elimination of most competition from most hubs and permits prices at such hubs to rise to high levels. Although exclusionary practices at hubs are currently being challenged by the Antitrust Division in its suit against American Airlines and are the subject of proposed guidelines that appear to be languishing at the Department of Transportation, we have to assume that fortress hubs are a continuing part of the industry landscape. (3)Entry barriers are relatively high. There was a time, in the 1980's, when it was believed by some economists that because the equipment for air transit was so mobile, entry to any overpriced route would be easy and we would not have to worry about concentration. Indeed, numerous airline mergers were permitted on the basis of this so-called 'contestable markets" theory, including several that the Department of Transportation approved over the objection of the Antitrust Division. What has become clear since the 80's is that contestable markets theory was catastrophically wrong. Entry is not easy. (No new entrant has been able to get into Reagan National Airport in 15 years. Gates at many airports, especially hubs, are unavailable.) Market power in the air transportation context has proved to be persistent and durable. The single most successful example of new entry, Southwest, has rested on a strategy of offering point-to-point service using non- hub terminals so as to confront the majors indirectly rather than head-on. (4)The major airlines often collaborate in ways that can reduce the intensity of competition. For example, the "T-2" joint venture now being constructed to offer electronic travel services, may have the ultimate impact of destroying independent ticket agencies and electronic alternatives such as Expedia, Priceline, and Travelocity. If this occurs, consumers will lose the independent "navigator" that can help them find the lowest fares and the least expensive alternative routes, something that is particularly valuable in an industry where there are so many prices and so many routes that information overload and information manipulation can be effective sales tools. It is reported that the Antitrust Division is investigating this joint venture. You can tell the story of domestic airline competition in three different ways: (1) we have a competitively structured air system that is continually finding new ways to enhance efficiency and better serve consumers; or (2) we have a system that is in reality far less competitive than it appears to be, and is already the locus of so much market power that consumers are not well-served; or (3) we have a system that contains important elements of both collaboration and rivalry, but in which rivals are constantly seeking ways to reduce the intensity of competition. If the first story is the true one, then a merger of the first and the sixth airlines might not be terribly threatening to competition. If the second view is correct, then this merger can only make a bad situation worse and must clearly be blocked. But if, as I believe to be the case, the third view is most accurate, we need to scrutinize this merger with great care in order to weigh the facts and reach a firm conclusion on its ramifications. 2. What effect will this merger have on the industry and on consumers? The Clayton Act is an incipiency statute. The Congressional intent was for the law to stop mergers whose effect substantially "may" be to lessen competition. By its choice of language and legislative history, Congress made clear that it did not want law enforcement to wait until the damage has already been done and it did not want a standard of absolute certainty. Congress understood that prediction is inherent in the process of merger evaluation. The Clayton Act invites the Antitrust Division to take into account all of the likely effects of a merger. For example, if the United/USAirways deal were likely to trigger additional deals, it would be relevant to the determination of whether the United acquisition should be permitted. Recall that United, Delta, and American are currently more or less equals. News reports strongly suggest that American and Delta are already investigating counter-strategic mergers, both with others and with each other, in response to the dramatic expansion of United that will be accomplished if the merger is permitted. If American and Delta believe that they must maintain some rough size parity in order to maintain competitive parity, then additional mergers are reasonably likely. This presents a difficult problem for the Antitrust Division. It should not stop the United merger based on mere speculation about the future; but it should not close its eyes to reasonably strong evidence that other mergers will quickly follow. The confounding fact is, to let the merger go through represents as much a prediction as a decision to stop it. A decision to approve the merger, even with conditions, should not be made without also having an answer to the next question: if this merger is approved, how can the following merger or the one after that be disapproved? Will we ever draw a line and if not here, where? Even if the Antitrust Division were to conclude that the United/USAirways merger is not likely to trigger additional mergers, it should also focus on the effects of the merger on potential competition. Might USAirways be one of a small number of potential competitors that could enter the concentrated markets of other large carriers? If so, it may have an impact as a potential competitor on competition in markets where it does not presently compete. The likelihood of this needs to be examined because it is doubtful that a smaller newcomer will be able to play a similar role for many years. Conversely, United claims that it needs to expand into the northeast so that it can better serve consumers. Perhaps United itself should be viewed as an important potential entrant whose ability to enter from outside, without a merger, has an effect that should not be easily dismissed. The impact of this merger on consumers will depend on many factors. Those most immediately at risk, of course, are people who depend on airports that are currently served by both United and USAirways and who will find themselves deprived of one of what had already been a limited number of choices. It should be stressed that choice is what competition is all about. Price is often a workable proxy for choice, but even if price were taken off the table in this transaction through a meaningful promise not to raise prices, consumers would still be impacted in a negative way by the reduction of options. Why is it that when an airplane lands and taxies toward the terminal, the steward or stewardess so often announces, "Thank you for flying with ABC Airline. We know you have a choice and we want you to choose us again next time you fly." I think this mantra recognizes that consumers are aware that in fact they really have few choices, but that choice is important to them. If we were to go from six major airlines to five, an important element of choice would be lost. But how often does a given consumer booking a given trip actually have six airlines to choose among? And if this merger triggers others, how much choice will be lost? My point is that merger enforcement cannot hide from the need to make predictions. The Antitrust Division must collect as much information as possible that will help it to make the best predictions it can and then it must boldly make a judgment. Some of its information will not be public and cannot be made public, but the public will be owed an explanation of what prediction the Division ultimately relied upon and the reasoning by which it reached its judgment. 3. Is there a viable remedy short of blocking the merger? Most mergers today are either permitted to be consummated or are conditionally approved, subject to the divestiture of overlapping assets. It is reported that United has proposed two concessions in order to take antitrust issues off the table. First, it will hold prices in place for two years. Second, it will spin off certain assets at Reagan National Airport in order to create a new regional carrier to be based there. Before addressing these proposed concessions, it is necessary to put the matter in perspective. The Clayton Act is violated whenever competition may be substantially lessened in any line of commerce or in any geographic market. If there is one geographic market where the illegal effect may occur, the merger is technically illegal. Now, the agencies typically don't act on this severe interpretation because it would be wasteful of resources. If there were a minor overlap in one small market, and the whole merger were blocked, this would be easy to fix by selling off an offending asset and starting the merger all over again. To avoid this inefficient process, the antitrust agencies routinely negotiate with merging parties to fix the identified problem areas, without sending the parties back to square one. The agencies have substantial bargaining power, however, since they do have the right to go to court to try to stop a merger. They must use this power to ensure that the merger will not be likely to lessen competition. It isn't enough that the recipient of divested assets be "viable"; divested assets must also be employed so that they pose the same threat to coordinated interaction and the same level of choice to consumers, as is now provided by USAirways. This is the standard against which United's proposals should be measured. I stress this question of divestiture effectiveness because it has become an important issue in antitrust policy in recent years, with particular attention brought to a head in a significant FTC staff study released last August. The study found that many divestitures that had been accepted by the FTC as conditions of approving a merger turned out not to preserve competition very well. In consequence, there has been a trend of the agencies paying more attention to this aspect of merger enforcement. Congress should be encouraging this trend and insisting that any divestitures that may be conditions for this merger to be approved will indeed be robust for competition. With respect to the two-year moratorium on price increases, the Antitrust Division should be skeptical. If there is not a likelihood of a price increase flowing from the merger, one wonders why United raised the issue? The merger, like a diamond, may be forever. If this merger makes it possible for United to raise prices in year three, as a result of increased market power, then it should be blocked and the two-year concession rejected. But in an industry where price discrimination is so sophisticated and widespread, it is also necessary to ask, what is meant by a price freeze? The mix of seats sold at different prices changes daily, sometimes hourly. To hold one seat at a low price while selling many more at a higher price, albeit no higher than the current highest price, would be a gimmick of no substantive value to consumers. To enforce a price freeze in this context would be very difficult if not impossible. What about spinning off assets to a new airline that can fly in and out of Reagan National? Unless the new airline will be at least as efficient as USAirways, it will not be able to replace USAirways as a competitor. The relevant questions appear to be: (a) Will this new airline have enough assets to survive? (b) Will the assets be sufficiently independent of United so that they can be used in direct competition against United? (c) Will the assets include enough valuable routes so that the carrier can survive? (d) Will the carrier have sufficiently competent and air-expert management to survive in a market place that will probably quickly come to include more competition from low-price Southwest and from new regional jets? Or, put another way, from the viewpoint of the consumer, will this start-up realistically be able to step into USAirways' much larger shoes? This question in itself subsumes another: what would be the fate of USAirways in the absence of this merger? Clearly, it has not always flown in calm skies and there has been speculation about its future. The Antitrust Division will again have to make a prediction and the public will again be entitled to an explanation of the prediction. If USAirways 'in effect has no future as a viable competitor, antitrust policy will have less reason to seek the continuity of its franchise. This is not to suggest the presence of a "failing company" defense, which is well recognized in the antitrust law but is apparently not being claimed here, or of a "floundering company" defense, which in any event is not recognized. It is, rather, to say that the public has a right to expect that any airline to which is divested assets of USAirways will in fact be able to step into the competitive shoes of USAirways. There is a final question we would pose: if the, merger is to be allowed to go through, what are the best means for assuring that divestitures result in no loss of competition? is it by allowing United to spin off selected assets to a hand-chosen competitor? Is it by auction of slots? And of course this question must be asked with regard to each route in which the merger will raise concentration to unhealthy levels. Conclusion Determining whether this merger is legal or how it can be made legal through various conditions that might be imposed, requires the Antitrust Division to undertake a detailed evaluation of facts and to make sophisticated predictions. A thorough analysis, in our opinion, requires consideration of USAirways' ability to survive as a competitive airline, its role as a potential competitor, United's role as a potential competitor, and the likelihood that this merger will trigger additional mergers. Ultimately, what is required is a vision of how concentrated we will allow the market for domestic air transportation to become. This can be established in the course of antitrust analysis or it can become established by specific act of Congress. But once an industry becomes as concentrated as air transportation, it makes no sense to treat each merger on an ad hoc basis without a larger vision of where we are headed.

LOAD-DATE: July 3, 2000, Monday




Previous Document Document 48 of 110. Next Document


FOCUS

Search Terms: United Airlines AND U.S. Airways AND Merger, House or Senate or Joint
To narrow your search, please enter a word or phrase:
   
About LEXIS-NEXIS® Congressional Universe Terms and Conditions Top of Page
Copyright © 2002, LEXIS-NEXIS®, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.