|
The e-Freedom
Coalition's Proposal to the Advisory Commission on Electronic
Commerce (abridged) by Staff on
11/10/99 of
e-Freedom
Coalition Topic:
General, e-Freedom
Coalition proposal |
I Electronic commerce
has grown rapidly over the past several years. The Internet is
changing the way the world does business. From the perspective of
the online consumer, it does not matter if a purchase is made from a
Web site in San Francisco, Boston, or Beijing — it only matters who
offers the best product at the best price. Everyone — including
government — gains from such increasing economic
integration.
Unfortunately,
the benefits of electronic commerce are threatened by the impulses
of some elected officials to regulate and tax. Electronic commerce
is changing daily in scope and scale: in the way the industry is
structured, the ways information is formatted and transmitted, the
ways in which exchanges are created and financed, and the ways in
which privacy is protected. Every aspect of electronic commerce is
in flux. We believe any effort to assert political control is an
assault on this emerging medium. We believe taxes on remote sales
will inevitably entail vast and invasive monitoring – Who would levy
the tax; what level of tax and of record-keeping would be imposed;
how would compliance and sales be monitored. Furthermore, tax
proposals pose severe threats to the evolving privacy protections on
the Internet such as encryption and anonymous digital money.
Those are reasons enough for
caution. But the problems with e-commerce taxation go far beyond its
invasiveness. Indeed, allowing state and local governments to tax
across borders is fundamentally unjust. Remote taxation isTaxation
without Representation on an unprecedented scale; a practice that
cannot be tolerated in democratic society. The proper role of
taxation is to support those functions carried out within a
governing jurisdiction. Such taxes cannot be levied on or collected
from people who have no say in how the funds are used. Imposing tax
collection responsibilities on remote firms violates those important
principles by staking claim on economic activity largely unrelated
to the benefits provided by the taxing jurisdiction.
The advocates of new tax
collection schemes rely on an increasingly irrelevant distinction
between so-called "Main Street" businesses and online business. But
the Internet is open to everyone. Even as the Commission
deliberates, Main Street businesses are embracing the Internet in
droves, through individual Web sites, online auctions, and such
emerging forums as Amazon's zShops and Iconomy.com's automated
storefronts. In the name of the small number of Main Street
businesses that would stifle rather than embrace the opportunities
presented by the Internet, the proponents of new tax collection
schemes are willing to sacrifice the ability of future Main
Streeters to reach the world via the information highway. If the
advocates of expanded taxation prevail, many main Street businesses
will stay precisely that – never reaching their full potential in
the increasingly global marketplace.
Proposals to apply "efficient" or "uniform" taxes to remote
sales are especially distressing. A uniform tax is easily raised and
high tax rates, even when administered on a neutral basis, are
detrimental to economic growth and development. Electronic commerce
empowers consumers to take advantage of competitive tax rates in
other jurisdictions and thus serves as a necessary constraint on
excessive government. The flexibility in moving capital and economic
activities around the globe offered by the Internet at last makes it
possible to sharpen those disciplining influences.
For those officials concerned
about "leakage" from state and local taxes due to Internet commerce,
the solution is a re-examination of their own tax-and-spending
policies. The first priority should be to cut unnecessary
expenditures and streamline tax collection systems. Indeed, it is
abundantly clear in this time of unprecedented federal, state and
local budget surpluses that the last thing politicians need are new
revenues. Rather than impose new
and onerous tax collection schemes, we take a more open approach
that respects the sovereignty of both taxpayers and local
jurisdictions.
Recognizing
that a citizen's ability to take advantage of all the Internet
offers, including e-commerce, completely depends on the Internet's
accessibility, this proposal contains five recommendations to tear
down and prevent the re-emergence of government-imposed taxes and
regulations that serve only to drive up costs for consumers and
retard the investments needed to strengthen and maintain the
national information infrastructure. Specifically, we have
identified five tax-related barriers to Internet access:
1. Barrier #1: The federal 3%
excise tax on telecommunications. The tax is an anachronism and should be repealed
immediately.
2. Barrier #2: Discriminatory ad
valorem taxation of interstate telecommunications.
Fifteen states tax
telecommunications business property at rates higher than other
property, driving up costs for consumers. Federal protections
against such taxes – already in effect for railroads, airlines and
trucking -- should be extended to telecommunications.
3. Barrier #3: Internet tolls – new
taxes and fees levied on telecommunications providers and their
customers when cable is installed along highways and roads.
These new taxes, which can run
up to 5% of gross receipts, drive up costs for consumers, and
should be abolished. Congress should make clear that the 1996
Telecommunications Act intended only for state and local
governments to be reimbursed for actual costs incurred for
managing public rights of way.
4. Barrier #4: High state and local
telecommunications taxes, complicated auditing and filing
procedures. Many governments
are using consumer telephone bills as cash cows, imposing multiple
and high taxes on services. Such taxes should be slashed to a
single tax per state and locality, and filing/auditing procedures
streamlined.
5. Barrier #5: Internet access
taxes. The temporary federal
ban on Internet access taxes should be made permanent. States and
localities that imposed such taxes before the ban took effect
should repeal any taxes on access to keep costs down for
consumers.
Next, we
propose that if sales taxes are to continue to be collected online,
a pro-growth system for the collection of sales and use taxes by
companies with a substantial physical presence within the taxing
jurisdiction is appropriate. The system would affirm, update and
clarify existing constitutional law by setting clear jurisdictional
standards that are relevant and easily understood in "new economy."
Originally proposed by Commissioner Dean Andal, this proposal will
encourage tax collection by minimizing the compliance burden while
at the same time encourage expansion of e-commerce by improving the
certainty of state and local tax responsibilities.
In short, our proposal hinges
on many of the principles that have prevailed in fostering the
Internet's own phenomenal growth: openness, fairness, accessibility,
freedom, and the minimal involvement of political institutions. We
now propose taking the Internet into the next century by increasing
its accessibility, encouraging the growth of e-commerce, and
enabling tax collection within proper constitutional
guidelines.
A Clear,
Constitutional Approach to e-Commerce Taxation
- The E-Freedom Coalition recommends
that the temporary tax-free zone arrangement created by the
Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA) be made permanent for both access
taxes and sales or use taxes on electronic commerce. Moreover, the
Advisory Commission should recommend that any existing state or
local taxes that were grandfathered under the ITFA be phased out
or repealed outright.
The economic arguments against taxing electronic commerce are
strong. First, such taxation is inefficient. Imposing multiple,
overlapping or discriminatory access or sales taxes on the Internet
or electronic commerce in general would be extremely difficult and
inefficient in practice. Having 30,000 or even just 50 tax
jurisdictions and policies would create a confusing and
counter-productive domestic tax regime. Imposing such a tax regime
on the Internet or electronic commerce would also have an extremely
deleterious effect on the Internet sector just as it is beginning to
grow and expand. Industry output and entrepreneurship would likely
be greatly curtailed as a result.
The negative effects of a new Internet tax regime would
reverberate throughout the national economy. Almost every American
industry is now engaged in some form of electronic commerce or has
initiated Internet-based services. Imposing burdensome taxes on
Internet access or sales would discourage further efforts in this
regard and likely retard innovation, job creation, and economic
growth in general.
The
creation of such a tax regime or regimes would likely require a
significant increase in government tax oversight and enforcement
efforts. Tax collection agencies at all levels of government would
grow larger and more intrusive as efforts to tax electronic commerce
proliferated. The resulting expansion in the overall size of
government would likely lead to more government meddling in the
private sector in general and the high-tech sector in particular.
Just as the economic
arguments against Internet taxation are strong, so are the legal and
constitutional arguments. The Supreme Court has long held that
attempts by a state or local government to tax or regulate
out-of-state activity or "remote commerce" are unconstitutional.
State and local governments can only tax those parties that have a
"nexus" or "substantial physical presence" within their
jurisdictions. Establishing a tax system that grants state and local
governments the right to impose multiple and over-lapping taxes
would reverse two centuries worth of sound Supreme Court case law
and create a disturbing precedent for the taxation of other forms of
interstate commerce.
Beyond
upsetting legal precedent, taxing electronic commerce represents a
direct affront to constitutional first principles and a threat to
America's federalist structure of government in general. The
Founding Fathers included language in Article 1, Section 8 of the
Constitution to allow Congress to "regulate interstate commerce" in
an attempt to remedy the problems the colonies experienced when they
operated under the Articles of Confederation. Excessive parochialism
and perpetual interference with the free flow interstate commerce
forced the Founders to abandon the Articles and instead adopt our
modern Constitution to alleviate these ills. The federal republic
they created allowed for extensive state and local experimentation
and autonomy, but also placed firm limits on the ability of state
and local governments when interstate commerce was at stake. An
important part of America's federalist system of government,
therefore, is an understanding and appreciation of the limits of
state sovereignty. In order for each state to preserve an autonomous
sphere for itself, there must necessarily be limits on its
jurisdictional authority. Simply put, a state's jurisdictional
authority ends at its own borders. Allowing state or local taxation
of the Internet would betray this constitutional first principle by
allowing governments to impose their will on consumers and companies
outside their jurisdictional boundaries.
For these economic and legal reasons, it is vital
that the Advisory Commission propose a permanent ban on access taxes
or any form of discriminatory sales or use taxes on electronic
commerce.
Addressing and
Debunking the "Fairness" Arguments
Despite these arguments, some members of the
Advisory Commission may still resist the adoption of a permanent ban
on Internet access and sales taxes because of certain "fairness"
arguments they have heard repeatedly voiced by critics of the
Internet Tax Freedom Act. These fairness arguments typically come in
two varieties:
1. Fairness Argument #1: It is not
fair to exempt remote Internet vendors from access or sales taxes
when "bricks and mortar" or "Main Street" businesses within a
state are required to pay them.
2. Fairness Argument #2: It is not
fair to deprive state and local governments of the revenues that
could be collected by taxing Internet access or electronic
sales.
These
arguments represent legitimate concerns that are being raised by a
host of state and local government officials and some Main Street
businesses. Therefore, it is important that the members of the
Advisory Commission address and debunk these fairness arguments to
ensure that taxes are not imposed on electronic
commerce.
The first argument
regarding the fairness of exempting remote vendors from access or
sales taxes misses an important point: remote vendors do not use or
deplete state or local resources which state or local taxes support.
In fact, it would be patently unfair to force out-of-state companies
to pay taxes for government services or programs they do not use or
benefit from. State and local businesses pay or collect such taxes
because they can take advantage of the programs or services provided
with those funds. Remote vendors engaging in interstate electronic
transactions do not benefit in a similar way from these taxes, and
shipping companies already pay taxes to cover their use of public
goods and services.
Moreover,
Internet vendors are tangible "bricks and mortar" businesses that
will continue to pay routine income taxes where they reside. A
permanent Internet tax moratorium would only exclude states and
localities from taxing remote vendors of electronic commerce.
The second fairness argument
regarding the threat a Net tax moratorium would pose for future
state and local tax revenues is equally flawed. The remarkable and
explosive rise of the Internet and electronic commerce is creating a
virtually unprecedented level of entrepreneurship and innovation in
America. Moreover, this remarkable technological renaissance has
been the driving engine behind America's recent strong and sustained
economic growth.
This has
presented policymakers with a paradoxical situation. The rise of
this new unregulated and, for the most part, untaxed industry
sector, has helped fuel the sustained growth of not only economic
activity, but government tax revenues as well. For the first time in
decades, Americans now live in an "Age of Surplus," where federal,
state, and local governments are taking in record tax revenues. How
can this be if critics are correct in their contention that a
tax-free Internet represents a serious drain on governmental tax
collections?
Simple economics
explains the apparent paradox. First, the rise of the Internet and
the Information Economy has created new jobs and new business
opportunities that did not exist previously. In turn, this increased
economic activity and output increased individual income and
business profits, which, consequently, provided new tax sources and
higher revenues overall for all governments. And, again, it is
important to reiterate that simply because interstate Internet
transactions have been exempted from taxes, that does not mean
companies engaging in electronic commerce are completely tax-free.
Electronic vendors are still responsible for paying routine
corporate income taxes and are treated like any other business
within their home states. A permanent moratorium on Net taxes would
not upset this balance in any way.
Setting a Uniform Jurisdictional Standard for
Sales Tax Collection
The
mission of the Advisory Commission on Electronic Commerce is to
"conduct a thorough study of Federal, State and local, and
international taxation and tariff treatment of transactions using
the Internet and Internet access and other comparable intrastate,
interstate, and international sales activities." The Commission has
been directed to report its findings to Congress, along with "such
legislative recommendations as required to address the
findings."
A recommendation
presumes a goal toward which our efforts are directed. This
recommendation is directed at a simple goal: promoting the expansion
of economic activity and opportunity through electronic commerce.
Achieving that goal does not require abandoning state and local
taxing authority, only better defining it. By placing clear
parameters on state and local authority to tax interstate commerce,
Congress can reduce the threat of taxation in jurisdictions in which
a business does not have a substantial physical presence. The U.S.
Supreme Court has long recognized that the Commerce Clause requires
a physical connection between the taxing jurisdiction and the
taxpayer. See Complete Auto
Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 430 U.S.
274 (1977). A substantial physical presence provides an identifiable
standard that ensures a state's power to tax is limited to taxpayers
within its borders. Nothing will do more harm to the growth of
electronic commerce than expanding state and local taxing authority
beyond their borders.
The
threat of taxation is as much an issue as the obligation of taxation
itself. The Supreme Court's decisions in National Bellas Hess, Inc. v. Department of Revenue of
Illinois, 386 U.S. 753 (1967),
and Quill Corp. v. North
Dakota, 504 U.S. 298 (1992), have
not been uniformly adhered to or interpreted. States continually
litigate new theories in the hope of expanding their jurisdiction
beyond their borders, not just for use taxes but other excise and
business activity taxes. The cost to taxpayers in money and time is
substantial. All the while, predictable jurisdictional standards are
being eroded. This lack of certainty is the biggest threat to
business on the Internet. One of the biggest hurdles facing
businesses engaged in interstate commerce is simply knowing which
tax agencies are involved. For the on-line business, the uncertainty
is positively mind-boggling because the technology itself poses new
questions in jurisdictional standards. Can an ISP that facilitates
the processing of data cause its customers to have tax obligations
in the state, county and city of the ISP? Does the mere fact that a
customer can order via your web page subject your company to
taxation in the state of the consumer? What about the in-state use
of a license or copyrighted material?
With the exception of PL 86-272, which relates
strictly to state income taxes and to sellers of tangible personal
property, Congress has left the question of the limits of state
taxing authority to the courts. The courts, however, have failed to
solve the problem. Each decision is the subject of subsequent
dispute and argument over its proper application. New theories are
developed and more time and energy spent litigating for certainty
and predictability.
The
definition of "substantial nexus" is most often the subject of
dispute. Some decisions suggest that it applies differently
depending on the type of tax. While the Supreme Court in Quill
reiterated the standard of a "substantial physical presence"
articulated in the 1967 decision of National Bellas Hess, 386
U.S. 753, some states argue their standard only applies to the
collection obligation under the use tax, and not, for example, to
income taxes. See Geoffrey, Inc.
v. South Carolina Tax Commission,
437 S.E.2d 13 (S.C. 1993), cert. den., 510 U.S. 992 (1993) (foreign corporation's licensing of
its Toys 'R Us trademark in the taxing state and the royalties
generated from it established nexus even without a physical
presence).
The indirect
establishment of a substantial presence on the part of the
out-of-state person is another fruitful ground of controversy. Over
the last decade, the states have attempted to expand the theory of
"attributional nexus," which attributes the substantial physical
presence of one person to that of another either by way of agency or
corporate affiliation. Does advertising by an out-of-state company
on a web page that happens to be on a server located in the taxing
state suffice? What about a logo on a web page "hot-linked" to an
out-of-state vendor? What about the in-state presence of a
telecommunications service provider's equipment used by an in-state
resident to order from an out-of-state vendor with whom the
telecommunications company contracts for services? For example,
Texas has asserted that a web site on a Texas server creates nexus
for an ISP's out-of-state customer.
Even if one assumes that jurisdiction to tax exists, the next
layer of uncertainty is what is subject to tax (tax base) and the
appropriate rate to apply. Computing the proper tax liability is the
most intrusive aspect of taxation and in many cases the most
burdensome aspect of taxation. The more tax agencies involved, the
more burdensome compliance becomes.
Unlike the bricks and mortar business that state and local
governments so often argue are being discriminated against, the
out-of-state retailer is asked to do that which the in-state
retailer is not: determine the place of use for each of its
customers. For example, the brick and mortar retailer doesn't ask if
I'm taking my purchase and going back to my home which is in a
different taxing jurisdiction. They don't care. The sales tax treats
the place of purchase as the place of consumption. However, if the
same transaction occurred online via the company's web page,
different standards would apply. If the store is in my home state,
most likely the sales tax would once again apply but the seller
would first have to determine the destination of the sale. If the
seller was in a different state, the use tax applies and the seller
would have to identify the destination of the sale and collect and
remit based on the rules and rates for that local jurisdiction
assuming the company has nexus (reliance on zip codes is not legally
sufficient as many zip codes cross taxing jurisdictions). In the
purely digital world, where both the consummation of the agreement
and the exchange of the product or service occur on-line, location
is not just irrelevant; it can be impossible to determine. The use
tax is not a surrogate consumption tax, as some would suggest. It
was a device conceived to protect in-state
merchants.
The physical
presence standard properly respects state borders. The basic purpose
of taxation is to raise money for government services and programs.
Why should a business, having no physical presence in a state, be
obligated to contribute to the programs and services in that state?
The argument of a "maintenance of a market" for the out-of-state
business mistakes the nature of that market. The market exists
because of the people, not the government (while such might be true
in a centrally planned economy, it is not the case in America). And
clearly, out of their own self-interest, the people who live in the
jurisdiction properly pay the taxes necessary to support the roads,
education and other infrastructure to meet the needs of that
market.
Subjecting taxpayers
to the intricacies of the tax codes of the jurisdiction in which
they are physically present is not an insignificant burden, but
subjecting taxpayers to all the tax codes in all the jurisdictions
of their customers would create an insurmountable burden to all but
the largest businesses.
Tear down the barriers to Internet access:
- Repeal the federal excise tax on
telecommunications
The federal 3% excise tax on telecommunications is an
anachronism that should be repealed immediately and in its
entirety.
The FET was
first established in 1898 as a temporary tax to help finance the
Spanish-American War, and then continued as a "luxury" tax to help
pay for World War I. Today, the FET is third behind alcohol and
tobacco as the largest general fund excise tax in the Federal
budget, raising nearly $5 billion in FY 1998. When state and local
taxes are taken into account, the average tax rate on
telecommunications services in the U.S. is over 18
percent.
Taxes on
telecommunications are, inevitably, taxes on the Internet. Whether
through dial-up access or Digital Subscriber Lines (DSL), over cable
modems or wireless ones, access to the Internet takes place over the
telecommunications network. Indeed, over 50 percent of the traffic
on the public switched telephone network is now comprised of data
rather than voice. Thus, high telecommunications taxes slow the
spread of Internet access and discourage deployment of the broadband
networks needed for the next generation of Internet growth. They
raise the costs of electronic commerce for every business, big or
small, and raise the price of Internet access for every household,
rich or poor.
Studies by the
Joint Committee on Taxation, the Congressional Budget Office and the
Treasury Department's Office of Tax Analysis have all concluded that
the FET is the most regressive of all federal taxes. A recent study
by The Progress & Freedom Foundation estimates that at least
165,000 U.S. households are priced out of the market for fast
Internet access due to high telecom taxes, with the impact falling
disproportionately on low-income and rural
households.
The FET also
discriminates against the very sector of the U.S. economy that is
driving economic growth. While the information technology sector of
the economy accounts for less than 10 percent of Gross Domestic
Product, it has produced over 40 percent of GDP growth in recent
years. Jobs created by the IT sector are among the highest paying
jobs in the U.S. economy, with average annual wages in excess of
$52,000, as compared with an economy-wide average of less than
$37,000.
- Prohibit the discriminatory ad valorem
taxation of interstate
telecommunications
With Internet access highly dependent on the
telecommunications backbone, any excessive taxes on
telecommunications ultimately restricts access to the Internet,
either through higher costs to users or under-investment
telecommunications infrastructure. Available and affordable Internet
access to Americans requires a nondiscriminatory tax burden on
telecommunications service providers.
Discriminatory property taxation usually takes two forms.
First, as part of the concept of unit valuation, many states tax the
intangible assets of public utilities while not taxing the same
assets held by other businesses. These intangible assets, which
include assets as diverse as federal operating licenses to an
assembled work force, are often the most valuable portion of the
utility's business. Second, states often apply a higher tax rate to
the tangible personal property held by utility companies than that
held by other business taxpayers generally. A recent study by the
Committee On State Taxation (COST) illustrates this
fact.1
The COST study found 15 states tax
telecommunications' tangible personal property at a higher rate than
other business property, and 14 states levy an ad valorem tax on
telecommunications intangible property at a higher rate than other
business intangibles.
The
impact of discriminatory property taxation victimizes customers in
several ways. Costs are exported to non-resident customers, driving
up nationionally-set long distance rates. As discriminatory taxes
are eventually passed to the consumer, they constitute a regressive
tax aimed at the nation's less fortunate citizens, who tend to spend
a higher portion of their incomes on utilities than wealthier
Americans.
Even if a strong
case against a discriminatory property tax could be made, current
federal law severely curtails such challenges being heard in federal
court unless an extremely high showing is made that the taxpayer has
no "plain, speedy and efficient remedy" available. As a result,
these taxpayers must file an appeal in the state court system and
perhaps multiple local administrative agencies often composed of the
same people who assess the property, thus making it more difficult
to gain a fair hearing. Without federal protections,
telecommunications companies are forced to pay the discriminatory
taxes before seeking judicial review.
The net result of all of these factors is a danger that
telecommunications companies will make inadequate investment in the
infrastructure backbone that is essential to the development of the
Internet. Discriminatory taxation of telecommunications property
reduces return on such property and investment in the Internet
backbone is diminished as a result. Improved customer access to the
Internet, the World Wide Web and electronic commerce will only come
through lower costs associated with increased competition and
adequate investment. Discriminatory property taxation of
telecommunications companies stands squarely in the way.
A federal legislative
proposal to extend 4-R property tax treatment to telecommunications
carriers engaged in interstate commerce is sorely needed to protect
investment in the Internet backbone. This proposal affords
telecommunications companies the same tax treatment as their
competitors for property tax purposes. Tax discrimination will be
eliminated and increased investment encouraged. Ultimately, this
policy will result in expansion of the Internet and improved access
for all Americans.
- Scrap Internet tolls: No above-cost fees
for the installation of telecommunications cable along
right-of-ways.
State
and local governments are using strained interpretations of the 1996
Telecommunications Act to impose "Internet tolls" in the form of new
"franchise taxes" of up to 5% on business and consumer
telecommunications use. With an average 18.2% transaction tax burden
already imposed,2 these new taxes and related special "fees" could
easily make telecommunications the most highly taxed product or
service in the United States. Given the critical role these services
play in accessing the Internet, such new taxes are a true impediment
to the growth of widespread access to and use of the Internet. The
Advisory Commission on Electronic Commerce must urge Congress to
take remedial action immediately to clarify the Telecommunications
Act of 1996 and to ensure state and local government tax policy is
not a major contributor to the digital divide evident
today.
Section 253(c) of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996 states that: "[n]othing in this
section affects the authority of a State or local government to
manage the public rights-of-way or to require fair and reasonable
compensation from telecommunications providers, on a competitively
neutral and nondiscriminatory basis, for use of public rights-of-way
on a nondiscriminatory basis, if the compensation required is
publicly disclosed by such government." Unfortunately, state and
local governments are routinely interpreting this language as
granting them authority to impose a whole new regime of taxation on
telecommunications providers and their customers.
Clearly, as found in a number
of recent federal district court cases,2 Congress intended this term
"compensation" to bear a direct relationship to the actual costs
incurred by state and local jurisdictions in managing
telecommunications facilities located in the public rights-of-way.
Clarification by Congress of what is meant by "fair and reasonable
compensation" is critical lest telecommunications providers will
continue to incur years of costly litigation as state and local
governments repeatedly attempt to impose new taxes never intended by
Congress in adopting Section 253(c).
Specifically, Section 253(c) should be amended to make clear
that state and local governments should be reimbursed only for their
actual and direct incremental expenses incurred in managing the
telecommunications providers' presence in the public rights-of-way.
Clearly, telecommunications providers and their customers should be
responsible for those expenses state and local governments incur in
managing the placement of facilities in the public rights-of-way.
And, just as clearly, Congress never intended state and local
government to create a new tax regime that creates barriers to
entry, discourages the development of facilities-based competitors
and makes it much more expensive for both businesses and consumers
to enjoy the benefits of advanced telecommunications services and
access to the Internet. Accordingly, this new and detrimental form
of taxation must be halted – this type of costly taxation can only
have the effect of slowing the growth of high-speed access to the
Internet.
Local governments
have also misinterpreted Section 253(c)'s language regarding
"authority . . . to manage the public rights-of-way" as providing
them with authority to introduce a third tier of regulatory
oversight. These attempts at local level regulatory oversight of
telecommunications services always result in the telecommunications
provider bearing significant and unnecessary costs. Local
governments have repeatedly attempted to impose
regulatory/management requirements on telecommunications providers
that translate into increased costs of doing business in the local
jurisdictions. Of course, these increased costs are passed along to
business and consumer users of telecommunications in the form of
increased rates – a hidden tax. These new local
regulatory/management requirements, e.g. mapping requirements,
facilities planning reports, provision of in-kind services,
undergrounding of facilities, do not constitute "manag[ing]. . . the
public rights-of-way" as envisioned by Section 253(c). Instead, as
with new "franchise" taxes, these new local regulatory/management
requirements have the effect of creating additional barriers to
entry, discouraging the development of facilities-based competitors
and making telecommunications services artificially more expensive.
Congress must clarify Section 253(c) to bar this third tier of
regulatory oversight.
Section
253(c) of the Telecommunications Act was never intended to be the
vehicle for erecting tolls on the information superhighway. The
Commission should urge Congress to clarify the law to ensure that
this abuse of telecommunications consumers is ended.
- Simplify state and local
telecommunications taxes, filing and auditing
procedures.
State
and local telecommunications taxes are too high, too complicated,
and too numerous. Consumers are burdened by multiple and often
regressive taxes on telecommunications while providers must cope
with complex filing and auditing procedures and in turn pass
compliance costs along to consumers.
The Commission should consider several ideas to reduce and
simplify state and local taxes on telecommunications. States and
localities that choose to tax telecommunications should impose only
a single tax (one for state, one for localities), with one low rate
and base applying across the state using uniform definitions
representing the components of taxable and exempt transactions and
customers. Providers should be required to file only a single return
to the state, representing funds collected for state and local
taxes, after which the state should distribute funds back to
localities. To further reduce compliance costs, only one audit per
state should be permitted for any taxable
period.
Additional means of
simplifying state and local telecommunications taxes should be
considered, but only when such simplification will not ultimately
increase the net tax burden, or rates, for consumers.
- Protect privacy: Restrict government from
collecting data on individual consumer transactions.
Protecting consumer
privacy is absolutely critical, and the best way to protect consumer
privacy is to make permanent the federal ban on discriminatory
e-commerce taxes as described above, or as separately proposed by
Chairman Gilmore and Rep. John Kasich. Any new, expansive tax
collection scheme is undesirable, regardless of whether "trusted
third parties" or some other "farming out" tax collection scheme us
utilized.
Under the proposal
we outline above, absolutely no personal information beyond the home
state of the consumer need ever be collected by a merchant, and only
then when the consumer resides in a state where the merchant meets
the nexus standard. We do find, however, that to the extent taxes
continue are collected within the constitutional framework discussed
above, the privacy of the consumer must be protected as well as or
better than in the analog world, which currently protects consumer
privacy by allowing for anonymous cash transactions. Developments in
privacy protection in the digital world, such as encryption, should
not be stifled by elaborate new tax schemes.
Any sales tax regime that requires personally
identifiable information to be collected or transmitted to any
government agency or surrogate should be summarily rejected.
Proponents of new tax collection regimes limply shield themselves
from criticism by claiming that compliance with their plan will be
"voluntary." Yet a thorough understanding of such proposals,
combined with a dose of realism, make clear that their systems will
not remain "voluntary" for long. We view claims that their sales tax
schemes will permanently protect consumer privacy with equal
skepticism.
In addition, we recognize a fundamental difference
between government collecting information on its citizens and two
private parties entering into a voluntary agreement. Clearly, a
merchant knowing you're a shopper's purchasing behavior for the
purpose of making sales recommendations stands distinct from the
government building a profile, for whatever reason, of you're a
shopper's purchases and activities. Consequently, government should
not interfere with the freedom of merchants and shoppers to
voluntarily collect information.
Endnotes 1-Committee On State Taxation,
50-State Study and Report on
Telecommunications Taxation,
September 7, 1999.
2 -Committee on State Taxation, 50-State Study and Report on
Telecommunications Taxation, Testimony before the Advisory
Commission on Electronic Commerce, September 14,
1999.
|
|
Proposals by Title
All Publications by Author by Date by Organization by Title by Topic |