Skip banner
HomeHow Do I?Site MapHelp
Return To Search FormFOCUS
Search Terms: tax w/5 foreign w/5 income, House or Senate or Joint

Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed

Previous Document Document 72 of 113. Next Document

More Like This
Copyright 1999 Federal Document Clearing House, Inc.  
Federal Document Clearing House Congressional Testimony

June 30, 1999

SECTION: CAPITOL HILL HEARING TESTIMONY

LENGTH: 2559 words

HEADLINE: TESTIMONY June 30, 1999 WILLIAM W. CHIP CHAIRMAN HOUSE WAYS AND MEANS INTERNATIONAL TAX RULES

BODY:
Statement of William W. Chip, Chairman, Tax Committee, European-American Business Council, and Principal, Deloitte & Touche LLP Testimony Before the House Committee on Ways and Means Hearing on Impact of U.S. Tax Rules on International Competitiveness June 30, 1999 My name is Bill Chip. I am a principal in Deloitte & Touche, an international tax, accounting, and business consulting firm. I have been engaged in international tax practice for 20 years. I am testifying today as Chairman of the Tax Committee of the European-American Business Council (EABC). The EABC is an alliance of 85 multinational enterprises with headquarters in the United States and Europe. A list of EABC members is attached. Because the EABC membership includes both US companies with European operations and European companies with US operations, the EABC brings a unique but practical perspective on how the US international tax rules impact the competitiveness of US companies operating in the European Union (EU) -- the world's largest marketplace. The points I would like to make today may be summarized as follows: 1. US international tax rules foster tax neutrality between US companies, but not between US companies and foreign companies. 2. In order for US-parented companies to be truly competitive in a globalized economy, the US should not impose a corporate income tax on income from foreign operations. 3. The enhanced power of the IRS to police transfer pricing has eliminated the most important rationale for the subpart F rules, which should therefore be relaxed. 4. The anticompetitive flaws in the US system cannot be fully corrected without attending to other problems, such as the taxation of dividends with no credit for corporate-level taxes. 5. Certain changes are urgently needed pending more fundamental reforms: (1) the EU should be treated as a single country under the subpart F rules; (2) the US should agree to binding arbitration of transfer pricing disputes; and (3) the rules for allocating interest between US and foreign income should be made economically realistic. 6. Many problems faced by US companies operating internationally cannot be resolved by US tax policy alone, and the US should take the lead in erecting an international tax system that does not impede cross-border business activity. The EABC welcomes the Chairman's interest in reforming this country's international tax rules. Those rules have always had a negative impact on the ability of US companies to compete overseas. However, this anticompetitive impact has been masked during most of this century by several US business advantages, including the world's largest domestic economy as a base, a commanding technological lead in many industries, and sanctuary from the destruction of two world wars. However, 50 years of peace and the rapid spread of new technologies have leveled these advantages and exposed the anticompetitive thrust of our international tax regime. I would go so far as to say that the US rules with respect to income produced overseas were written without any regard whatsoever for their impact on competitiveness. Their goal instead was to ensure that any income controlled by a US person was eventually subject to US tax. Thus, income of foreign subsidiaries is taxed at the full US corporate rate when distributed to the US parent (with a credit for any foreign income taxes) and then taxed again (with no credit for either US or foreign income taxes) when distributed to the US shareholders. The imposition of US tax is accelerated when foreign earnings are redeployed from one foreign subsidiary to another and also, under subpart F, when the foreign income is one of the many types that Congress feared could otherwise be "sheltered" in a "tax haven." These rules do have the effect of neutralizing the impact of foreign taxes on competition between US companies. Because all foreign earnings must eventually bear the full US tax rate, a US company that produces in a low-tax foreign jurisdiction enjoys at most a temporary tax advantage over one that produces in the US. Likewise, because all earnings of US companies eventually bear the same US corporate tax rate, the presence or absence of a shareholder-level credit for corporate taxes is immaterial in a shareholder's decision to invest in one US company rather than in another. In contrast, the US tax system does not neutralize the impact of taxes on competition between US and foreign companies. At the shareholder level, the absence of a credit for corporate-level taxes favors investments in low-taxed foreign companies over their US equivalents. At the corporate level, if the costs of producing a product, including tax costs, are lower in a foreign country such as Ireland than they are in the US, our free trade rules will likely result in US customers purchasing the Irish product rather than the equivalent US product. However, if a US owner of an Irish enterprise must also pay the excess of US over the Irish tax rate, then the Irish enterprise will likely end up being owned by a foreign company whose home country does not tax the Irish earnings, taxes them later, or provides a more liberal foreign tax credit. These competitive disadvantages are aggravated by business globalization. Owing to the internationalization of capital markets, an ever-larger percentage of US shareholders are able and willing to invest in foreign corporations and mutual funds, impairing the ability of US companies to raise capital for their overseas operations even in the US capital markets. The electronic revolution in communications and computing has also globalized the economic production process. Economic output is increasingly the consequence of coordinated activity in a number of different countries, expanding the range of products impacted by anticompetitive tax rules. If the Irish enterprise in the foregoing example is an integral part of a global activity, US companies may lose the opportunity to sell, not only the Irish product, but also any integral US products. The US system leads to very anomalous results. Consider a US company with a German and Irish subsidiary, then consider three identical companies, except that the US and Irish companies are subsidiaries of the German company. The US would never dream of trying to tax the income of the Irish subsidiary in the second case, but in the first case insists on taxing it when the income is repatriated, if not sooner. There is no reason why this should be so. Most countries, like the US, have a progressive income tax for individuals and, above a certain level, a virtually flat income tax for corporations. That being the case, there is a reason for imposing shareholder-level taxes on dividends received from local and foreign corporations (although there should be a credit for taxes paid at the corporate level). There is no reason for imposing a local corporate tax on foreign earnings as they make their way from the foreign subsidiary to the ultimate individual shareholders. Nowhere is the anti-competitive burden imposed by US tax rules more evident and damaging than in the application of the US "subpart F" rules to US-owned enterprises in the EU. The subpart F rules were intended to prevent US companies from avoiding US taxes by sheltering mobile income in "tax havens." The impact of these rules is exacerbated by the fact that since 1986 any country with an effective tax rate not more than 90% of the US rate is effectively treated as a tax haven. Even the United Kingdom, an industrialized welfare state with a modern tax system, is treated as a tax haven by subpart F because its 30% corporate rate is only 86% of the US corporate rate. (If the US corporate tax rate when subpart F was enacted were the benchmark, the US today would itself be considered a tax haven.) Because Congress perceived that selling and services were relatively mobile activities that could be separated from manufacturing and located in tax havens, the "foreign base company" rules of subpart F immediately tax income earned by US- controlled foreign corporations from sales or services to related companies in other jurisdictions. Consider the impact of this rule on a US company that already has operations in several EU countries but wishes to rationalize those operations in order to take advantage of the single market. Such a company may find it most efficient to locate personnel or facilities used in certain sales and service activities in a single location or at least to manage them from a single location. While a number of factors will affect the choice of location, all enterprises, whether US- owned or EU-owned, will favor those locations that impose the lowest EU tax burden on the activity. However, if the enterprise is US-owned, the subpart F rules may eliminate any locational tax efficiency by immediately imposing an income tax effectively equal to the excess of the US tax rate over the local tax rate. Thus, US companies are penalized for setting up their EU operations in the manner that minimizes their EU tax burden (even though reduction of EU income taxes will increase the US taxes collected when the earnings are repatriated). It makes as little sense for the US to penalize its companies in this way as it would for the EU to impose a special tax on European companies that based their US sales and service activities in the US States that imposed the least tax on those activities. The subpart F rules were enacted mostly out of concern that certain types of income could readily be shifted into "tax havens." However, the term tax haven is misleading. Taxes are only one of many costs that enter into the production process and into the decision where to conduct a particular activity. Some countries have low taxes, but others have low labor or energy costs or a favorable climate or location. If an enterprise is actually conducted in a low-tax jurisdiction, it is anticompetitive for the US to impose (let alone accelerate) corporate taxes on the income properly attributable to that enterprise, just as it would be anticompetitive to impose a charge equal to any excess of US over foreign labor or energy costs. The imposition of taxes or other charges that offset the competitive advantage of the foreign enterprise will simply cause the enterprise to be owned by a non-US competitor that does not have subpart F rules. When subpart F was enacted, Congress seemed to be concerned that US companies might arbitrarily attribute excessive amounts of income to their low-taxed foreign operations. Whether or not such concern was warranted then, it is not warranted now. Since 1994 US companies have been subject to draconian penalties on any substantial failure to price their international transactions at arm's length. Moreover, most of our competitors, and even less developed countries such as Mexico and Brazil, have followed suit and greatly enhanced their enforcement of the arm's length standard. Having endowed the IRS with "weapons of mass destruction" in the field of transfer pricing, Congress can now afford to retire much of the obsolete subpart F armory. I would be remiss not to acknowledge that the globalization of business poses important challenges to tax administrators in the US and elsewhere. Ever greater shares of the nation's income derives from cross-border activity, while ever increasing integration of cross-border activity makes it harder to determining the source of business income. The IRS and most foreign tax authorities are well aware of these challenges and are working to surmount them. Indeed, the enhanced attention to transfer pricing is one of the more important and obvious responses to the globalization challenge. The efforts of the US and other countries to ensure receipt of their "fair share" of global tax revenues through transfer pricing enforcement points also to a need for increased international cooperation. For example, each country is likely to view arm's length transfer pricing as the pricing that maximizes the amount of local income. Hence the need for international mechanisms which ensure that the calculation of national incomes under national transfer pricing policies does not add up to more than 100% of a company's global income. Unfortunately, although all tax treaties provide a mechanism for reaching agreement on transfer pricing, very few require that the countries actually reach agreement, meaning there is no guarantee against double taxation. Even more unfortunately, the US is opposing such requirements. For example, while the EU countries have entered into a convention that requires arbitration of international transfer pricing disputes, the US has declined to exchange the notes that would effectuate the arbitration clauses of the few US tax treaties that have them. For that reason the EABC strongly recommends that the US enter into negotiations with the EU members states to extend the principles of the EU convention to transfer pricing disputes between the US and EU members. International cooperation does not mean that tax rates should be harmonized or even that the calculation of taxable income should be harmonized. In fact, unharmonized tax rates are a good thing, because tax competition is a useful counterweight to the many pressures on government to increase taxes and spending. For that reason the EABC shares many of the concerns outlined in the response of the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the report on "Harmful Tax Competition" by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). There is genuine alarm within the business community that some OECD members are responding in an anticompetitive way to the challenges of globalization. Rather than working cooperatively to construct an international tax system that ensures income is properly attributed to the jurisdiction where it originates and not taxed more than once, some countries seem more interested in maximizing the reach of their tax jurisdiction and capturing any income under the control of companies that are headquartered locally. The efforts of the present US Administration to expand the scope of subpart F by regulation and legislation reflect such an approach and should be rejected by the Congress. I am worried about a deep and growing divide between the business community and the tax authorities in many industrialized countries on how to manage the fiscal challenges of business globalization. At the EABC's recent Transatlantic Tax Conference, officials of the US, EU, and OECD discussed "harmful tax competition" and other current issues with tax leaders from BIAC and from leading US and EU business organizations. EU business was as frustrated with the inability of the EU member states to eliminate obstacles to cross-border business integration and dividend/royalty payments as was US business with IRS Notices 98- 11 and 98-35. All business representatives were concerned that the OECD seemed less intent on eliminating tax obstacles to an efficient international economy than on attempting to freeze in place existing revenue sources. The EABC welcomes attention by the US Congress to how the US tax system impacts business decisionmaking and is ready to work with your Committee to identify urgently needed reforms.

LOAD-DATE: July 6, 1999




Previous Document Document 72 of 113. Next Document


FOCUS

Search Terms: tax w/5 foreign w/5 income, House or Senate or Joint
To narrow your search, please enter a word or phrase:
   
About LEXIS-NEXIS® Congressional Universe Terms and Conditions Top of Page
Copyright © 2002, LEXIS-NEXIS®, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.