Statement on Foreign Sales Corporations (FSCs)


H.R. 4986, the FSC Repeal and Extraterritorial Income Exclusion Act of 2000

September 12, 2000

Mr. DeFAZIO. Mr. Speaker, let's briefly review why we find ourselves here today to debate replacing a rather arcane section of the tax code that allows corporations to avoid a portion of their tax bill by establishing largely paper entities in a filing cabinet in a tax haven like Barbados with the equally arcane tax provisions of H.R. 4986, the FSC Repeal and Extraterritorial Income Exclusion Act of 2000.

Creating this new, expanded loophole to assist corporations in escaping their fair share of the tax burden in the U.S. makes a mockery of pleas by my colleagues to simplify the tax code and improve fairness.

For nearly two decades, beginning with the Revenue Act of 1971 (P.L. 92-178), the U.S. provided tax incentives for exports. However, our trading partners complained that these incentives violated our commitments under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). While not conceding the violation, in 1984, Congress scrapped the Domestic International Sales Corporation (DISC) provisions and created the Foreign Sales Corporation (FSC) provisions. The differences are highly technical and probably only understood by international tax bureaucrats.

Under the FSC provision, corporations can exempt between 15 and 30 percent of their export income from taxation by routing a portion of their exports through a FSC. Our trading partners, specifically the European Union (EU), were not satisfied with the somewhat cosmetic changes made to the U.S. tax code.

Going back on a verbal gentlemen's agreement not to challenge our respective tax codes under global trading rules, the EU filed a complaint with the World Trade Organization (WTO), successor to GATT, essentially arguing the same thing that was argued about DISCs. Namely that export subsidies were illegal under global trading rules by conferring an unfair advantage on recipient companies.

A secretive WTO tribunal ruled against the U.S. Dutifully, the U.S. appealed the decision. Earlier this year, the WTO appeals panel upheld the earlier decision and ordered the U.S. to repeal the FSC provision or risk substantial retaliatory measures.

Specifically, the WTO appeals panel wrote, "By entering into the WTO Agreement, each Member of the WTO has imposed on itself an obligation to comply with all terms of that Agreement. This is a ruling that the FSC measure does not comply with all those terms. The FSC measure creates a `subsidy' because it creates a `benefit' by means of a `financial contribution', in that government revenue is foregone that is `otherwise due.' This `subsidy' is a `prohibited export subsidy' under the SCM Agreement [Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures] because it is contingent on export performance. It is also an export subsidy that is inconsistent with the Agreement on Agriculture. Therefore, the FSC measure is not consistent with the WTO obligations of the United States."

In other words, it is unfair and illegal under global trade rules for the U.S. tax code to provide welfare for corporations by allowing them to escape taxes that would otherwise be due.

At this point, one would expect that my colleagues who, on most occasions eloquently defend the need for "rules based trade" and "free markets", to adhere to the WTO directive and repeal FSC. Because I assumed my colleagues would want to be intellectually consistent, I introduced legislation shortly after the WTO ruling to repeal FSC.

After all, precedent proved the U.S. was more than willing to bend to the will of the WTO. When the WTO ruled against a provision of the 1990 Clear Air Act, the Environmental Protection Agency gutted its clean air regulations in order to allow dirtier gasoline from Venezuela to be sold in the U.S.

Similarly, when Mexico threatened a WTO enforcement action on a 1991 GATT case it had won that eviscerated the Dolphin Protection Act, the U.S. went along to get along. In fact, the Clinton Administration sent a letter to Mexican President Ernesto Zedillo declaring that weakening the standard by which tuna must be caught in "dolphin-safe" nets "is a top priority for my administration and me personally."

The WTO also ruled against the Endangered Species Act provisions that required U.S. and foreign shrimpers to equip their nets with inexpensive turtle excluder devices if they wanted to sell shrimp in the U.S market. The goal was to protect endangered sea turtles. The Clinton Administration agreed to comply with the ruling.

Given this record of acquiescing to the WTO, one could be forgiven for assuming the Clinton Administration and Congress would behave in a similar manner when losing a case on tax breaks for corporations.

Of course, sea turtles and dolphins don't make massive campaign contributions, or any campaign contributions for that matter. But, the large corporations who would be impacted by the WTO decision against FSCs do.

Apparently not bothered by the hypocrisy, immediately after the ruling by the WTO appeals panel, the Clinton Administration, a few Members of Congress, and the business community openly declared the need to maintain the subsidy in some form and began meeting in secret to work out the details on how to circumvent the WTO ruling and maintain these valuable, multi-billion dollar tax incentives.

Now, it is well-known that I am not a big fan of the WTO. It is an unaccountable, secretive, undemocratic bureaucracy that looks out solely for the interests of multinational corporations and investors at the expense of human rights, labor standards, national sovereignty, and the environment.

But, by pointing out that export subsidies like FSCs are corporate welfare, however, the WTO has done U.S. taxpayers a favor. Unfortunately, this legislation before us today only does wealthy corporations a favor.

I have several problems with H.R. 4986 besides the intellectual inconsistency. I will touch on each of these now.

First, and perhaps most importantly, there is little or no economic rationale for export subsidies like FSCs or the provisions of H.R. 4986. In its April 1999 Maintaining Budgetary Discipline report, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) noted "Export subsidies, such as FSCs, reduce global economic welfare and may even reduce the welfare of the country granting the subsidy, even though domestic export-producing industries may benefit."

Similarly, in August 1996, CBO wrote, "Export subsidies do not increase the overall level of domestic investment and domestic employment...In the long run, export subsidies increase imports as much as exports. As a result, investment and employment in import-competing industries in the United States would decline about as much as they increased in the export industries."

Need further evidence? The Congressional Research Service (CRS) has written "Economic analysis suggests that FSC does increase exports, but likely triggers exchange rate adjustments that also result in an increase in U.S. imports; the long run impact on the trade balance is probably nil. Economic theory also suggests that FSC probably reduces aggregate U.S. economic welfare."

Of course, protests will be heard from supporters of H.R. 4986 that it gets rid of the export requirement. In testimony before the Ways and Means Committee, Deputy Secretary Eizenstat said the Chairman's mark is "not export-contingent." Of course, that claim is absurd. If a company sells products solely in the U.S., they don't qualify for the tax subsidy. That is, by definition, an export subsidy. Therefore, the criticisms of export subsidies previously mentioned would apply to this new legislation as well.

President Nixon originally prosed export subsides, which became the DISC and then FSC, because he was alarmed at the size of the U.S. trade deficit, which was $1.4 billion in 1971, a number that seems almost quaint by today's standards. As Paul Magnusson noted in the September 4, 2000, Business Week, FSC "produced some hefty tax savings for big U.S. exporters, but it never did actually do much to narrow the trade deficit, which hit a record $339 billion last year." And which, I should add, has continued to set new records virtually every month this year.

I can't understand why it makes sense to subsidize U.S. exporters to the tune of $5 billion or more when the economic impact is "probably nil" or worse.

The economic rationale further deteriorates when one realizes, as the previous quotes suggest, that export subsidies discriminate against mom-and-pop stores who don't have the resources to export and against U.S. industries that must compete with imports. This means that export subsidies distort markets by pre-ordaining winners and losers. The winners? Large exporters and foreign consumers who get to enjoy lower priced U.S. products subsidized by U.S. taxpayers. The losers? Small businesses, U.S. taxpayers, and import-competing industries.

I find it interesting while Treasury has spent a great deal of time figuring out how to combat corporate tax shelters that have no economic rationale, as discussed in a July 1999 report, that they would push this corporate welfare, which also has no economic rationale.

So, who specifically benefits? The journal Tax Notes conducted a revealing study of FSCs in its August 14, 2000, edition. The article profiled the 250 companies that reported $1.2 billion in FSC tax savings in 1998. The top 20 percent of the companies in the sample claimed 87 percent of the benefits. The two largest FSC beneficiaries were the General Electric Company and Boeing, which saw their tax bills reduced by $750 million and $686 million, respectively from 1991-1998.

What are some of the other top FSC corporate welfare queens? Motorola, Caterpillar, Allied-Signal, Cisco Systems, Monsanto, Archer Daniels Midland, Oracle, Raytheon, RJR Nabisco, International Paper, and ConAgra. The list reads like a who's who of extraordinarily profitable multinational corporations. Hardly companies that should need to feed from the taxpayer trough.

Furthermore, American subsidiaries of European firms take advantage of U.S. taxpayers through export subsidies. British Petroleum, Unilever, BASF, Daimler Benz, Hoescht, and Rhone-Poulenc are all FSC beneficiaries. The fact that foreign companies can also claim export benefits pokes a large hole in the argument that these tax benefits are needed to ensure the competitiveness of U.S. businesses.

Similarly, isn't it a bit odd that economists and U.S. policymakers like to lecture European nations about their high tax burdens, but now, suddenly their tax burden is too low and, therefore, U.S. companies need subsidies in order to compete?

Let's be clear, this legislation is not about the competitiveness of large, wealthy, multinational corporations based in the United States. It is about wealthy campaign contributors wanting to keep and expand their $5 billion-plus tax subsidies and elected officials willing to do their bidding.

Not only does H.R. 4986 allow these companies to continue receiving billions in tax breaks, but it actually expands them. This legislation will cost U.S. taxpayers another $300 million a year or more.

It is also unfortunate that this legislation subsidizes a number of industries - such as defense contractors, tobacco companies, and pharmaceutical firms - that have no business receiving any more taxpayer hand-outs.

Take the defense industry, for example. Under the current FSC regime, defense contractors can only claim 50 percent of the tax benefit available to other industries. The legislation before us today allows the the full benefit available to others.

Leaving aside the fact that U.S. taxpayers are already overly generous to defense t they are, expanding this corporate welfare will have no discernable impact on overseas sales. The Treasury Department noted in August 1999, "We have seen no evidence that granting full FSC benefits would significantly affect the level of defense exports."

In 1997, the CBO made a similar point, "U.S. defense industries have significant advantages over their foreign competitors and thus should not need additional subsidies to attract sales."

Even the Pentagon has acknowledged this fact by concluding in 1994, "In a large number of cases, the U.S. is clearly the preferred provider, and there is little meaningful competition with suppliers from other countries. An increase in the level of support the U.S. government currently supplies is unlikely to shift the U.S. export market share outside a range of 53 to 59 percent of worldwide arms trade."

As Ways and Means Committee Member, Representative Doggett, noted in his dissenting views on H.R. 4986, "In 1999, without the bonanza provided by this bill, U.S. defense contractors sold almost $11.8 billion in weapons overseas - more than a third of the world's total and more than all European countries combined."

The U.S. should stop the proliferation of weapons and war, not expand it as this bill intends.

The pharmaceutical industry is another industry that does not need or deserve additional subsidies from U.S. taxpayers. The industry already receives substantial research and development tax credits as well as the benefits flowing from discoveries by government scientists. As Representative Stark noted in his dissenting views, drug companies lowered their effective tax rate by nearly 40 percent relative to other industries from 1990 to 1996 and were named the most profitable industry in 1999 by Fortune Magazine.

The industry sells prescription drugs at far cheaper prices abroad than here in the U.S. For example, seniors in the U.S. pay twice as much for prescriptions as those in Canada or Mexico. It is an affront to U.S. taxpayers to force them to further subsidize an industry that is already gouging them at the pharmacy as this bill would do.

In direct contradiction of various federal policies to combat tobacco related disease and death in the U.S., this legislation would force U.S. taxpayers to subsidize the spread of big tobacco's coffin nails to foreign countries. This violates the American taxpayers' sense of decency and respect. Their money should not be used to push a product onto foreign countries that kills one-third of the people who use it as intended.

By placing H.R. 4986 on the suspension calendar, debate is prematurely cut off and amendments to reduce support for drug companies, the defense industry or tobacco companies can not be considered. But, I guess that's just par for the course for a process that has taken place in relative secrecy between a few Members of Congress, the Administration, and the

Print Note: This page is excerpted from the web site of U.S. Representative Peter DeFazio, Fourth District, Oregon. http://www.house.gov/defazio/.