Skip banner Home   Sources   How Do I?   Site Map   What's New   Help  
Search Terms: broadband, open access, cable
  FOCUS™    
Edit Search
Document ListExpanded ListKWICFULL format currently displayed   Previous Document Document 6 of 16. Next Document

Copyright 2002 The Age Company Limited  
The Age (Melbourne)

May 23, 2002 Thursday

SECTION: Business; Pg. 3

LENGTH: 1282 words

HEADLINE: Too Late For Talk Of Telstra Break-up, So Labor's Calls Are Out Of Order

BYLINE: Stephen Bartholomeusz

BODY:
Labor, if reports are correct, appears to have forgotten that at the onset of the introduction of competition to the telecommunications industry it took a considered decision to leave Telstra as an integrated carrier.

It also appears to be unable to accept that, when the Howard Government privatised Telstra as an integrated carrier, the opportunity for politicians to revisit that original decision was surrendered.

And it appears unconcerned that two million shareholders, predominantly ordinary Australians, bought shares from the Federal Government on the basis that Telstra would remain an integrated carrier for the foreseeable future.

It may be that the reports of a discussion paper containing a series of radical proposals for carving up Telstra are misguided. The Opposition has, however, consistently talked about structural solutions to the "problem" of Telstra's dominance.

The report in yesterday's Sydney Morning Herald said options Labor would consider included selling Telstra's mobile and pay TV businesses to fund a buyback of its copper network, dividing it into a series of regional mini-telcos, divesting it of all but its fixed-line network, splitting it into separate retail and wholesale entities and funding its competitors to build networks of their own.

The common theme to those options is that Telstra has to be made smaller and weaker to create consumer benefit and an efficient industry.

As discussed last week, structural separation, no matter the model, doesn't necessarily achieve those objectives. Indeed it could undermine them.

Labor appears to have fallen for the same seductive pitch from Telstra's competitors that recently ensnared Richard Alston; that because the smaller players are finding conditions tough it inevitably follows that Telstra is abusing its position of dominance. That dominance flows from its ownership of the copper wire network.

There are, of course, other possible explanations for the inability of the smaller players to dance rings around a lumbering Telstra.

They include the possibility that some of the challengers aren't very good competitors; that some of them don't have financial resources to be playing in such a capital intensive industry, particularly after the dot-com and telco meltdown, and that the domestic market isn't big enough to sustain the number of players still jostling for position.

It is also possible that the access regime that allows Telstra's competitors to piggyback on its infrastructure isn't as effective as it might be, or at least as effective as Telstra's competitors would like it to be.

The other possibility, wild as it might sound, is that Telstra is a good competitor - that the combination of its brand and its ever-improving efficiency enable it to meet and beat competition that includes some of the world's bigger telcos. In areas where Telstra isn't regulated because it isn't dominant, it more than holds its own.

Fundamentally, the success of the deregulation of the sector cannot be measured by how many competitors there are, or how much money they make, or how quickly market share or profit can be stripped from Telstra (which would ultimately tie the success of deregulation to the failure of Telstra).

It should be judged by how much consumer benefit is created by the sector, Telstra included. In principle, competition could drive an enormous level of consumer and economic benefit while leaving an increasingly efficient and effective - and fairly competing - Telstra as dominant as ever.

All the objective data says that deregulation has generated substantial consumer benefit in the form of better and more efficient - and ever-cheaper - services, more service providers and considerable innovation and technological development.

As discussed last week, the latest thinking on telecommunications competition policy in the US has labelled structural separation a "non-remedy for a non-problem", and indeed suggested that it would create inefficiency and that its costs would exceed any benefits.

Telstra is an integrated telco, operating a digitised copper network with ADSL functionality, two wireless networks and a broadband cable. It has spent $20 billion in four years to build and upgrade those networks.

The networks are themselves integrated at a technological level - the wireless networks sit above and interact with the copper wire platform - and obviously interact at the corporate and customer level.

There are substantial economies and benefits of both scale and scope that flow from Telstra's size and its integrated model, some of which are shared with its competitors through the regulated-access regime and through the CPI-X formula used to cap and reduce prices in its core basic telephony businesses.

Its size and financial strength also give it balance-sheet strength and credibility - it is one of the most highly-rated telcos in the world - and enable it to make investments that would be beyond the capacity, or ambition, of most of its rivals in this market.

If Telstra is dismembered, whether it is carved up vertically or whether it is divided into a series of "baby-Telstras", those economies of scope and scale and that capacity to invest on the scale of recent years will be destroyed.

If its copper network were nationalised and used as a common platform for all comers, would there be the same capacity and incentive for entrepreneurial investment?

The incentives for the state-owned operator would be to maximise cashflows from the existing network, avoid risk, and therefore avoid being at the leading edge of technological developments.

Nothing would be built in the hope/belief that customers would come - utilities only invest for near-certain returns - and the distancing of the investment decisions from the end-customers would slow innovation.

Funding, presumably with taxpayer funds, Telstra's competitors (including the Singapore Government-controlled SingTel Optus?) surely isn't even being considered by Labor or anyone else.

Quite apart from the fact that there is no evidence that structural responses to Telstra's continuing dominance of basic telephony would benefit anyone but its competitors - it could simply shift value from Telstra's shareholders to them without consumer gain - the sector is a dynamic one.

Already it would appear that wireless is increasingly substitutable for the copper network. With SingTel Optus and Vodafone owning their own wireless networks, and Hutchison building a 3G network to go with its existing CDMA network, there is plenty of competition and innovation. There are even wireless local loops being rolled out to attack Telstra in its heartland.

SingTel has a broadband cable, which could be digitised and already carries voice and data, the free-to-air broadcasters are digitising their signals, and the Telstra broadband cable could also be digitised within an open-access regime. Plus there is satellite capacity.

There isn't, therefore, a shortage of communications capacity, which virtually ensures there will be increasing intensity of competition across the range of communication services. Or at least the opportunity for competitors to compete.

It would be a tragedy for Telstra, its shareholders and ultimately its customers if, in their enthusiasm to promote Telstra's competitors, politicians from either side of Parliament created a less efficient, dynamic and ambitious sector and destroyed value within Telstra for no good reason, or at least no certain and substantial gain.

The success of deregulation was never meant to be measured in terms of the damage it inflicted on Telstra. Nor should it be.

bartho@theage.com.au



LOAD-DATE: May 22, 2002




Previous Document Document 6 of 16. Next Document
Terms & Conditions   Privacy   Copyright © 2003 LexisNexis, a division of Reed Elsevier Inc. All Rights Reserved.