Economic Research Service logo Jump over Nav Bar
search  
Home Research Emphases Key Topics Briefing Rooms Publications Data Site Map About ERS
USDA's Farm Bill Gateway
ers analysis
peanuts
ERS Farm Bill image

 

Key changes
The 2002 Farm Act substantially revamped the peanut program. Under previous legislation, the peanut program was a two-tier price support program based on nonrecourse loans. Production for domestic edible consumption was limited to an annually established quota designed to uphold prices at the $610-per-ton quota loan rate. Nonquota (additional) peanut production was permitted only for export or domestic crush and was eligible for an "additional" loan rate of $132 per ton (in 2001). Under the 2002 Farm Act, the marketing quota system is eliminated and peanuts are treated similarly to "program" crops, such as grains and cotton—with identical marketing loan provisions available to all peanut producers. Farmers no longer have to own or rent peanut marketing quota rights to produce for domestic edible consumption. Compensation (a buy-out) is provided to quota holders for elimination of the peanut quota system. All farmers with a history of peanut production during 1998-2001, whether quota holders or not, are eligible for fixed direct payments and counter-cyclical payments based on an established target price.

Summary of provisions
A marketing assistance loan program is available for peanut producers—with or without a history of peanut production—for any quantity of peanuts produced on the farm. The peanut loan rate is fixed at $355 per ton. Producers can pledge their stored peanuts as collateral for up to 9 months and then repay the loan at a rate that is the lesser of 1) $355 per ton plus interest or 2) a USDA-determined repayment rate designed to minimize loan forfeiture, government-owned stocks, and storage costs. Alternatively, the producer may forgo the marketing loan and opt for a loan deficiency payment (LDP) at a payment rate equal to the difference between the loan rate and the loan repayment rate.

For producers with a history of peanut production, a direct payment of $36 per ton of eligible base-period (1998-2001) production is available. Eligible production would equal the product of average or assigned base-period yields (with the option of substituting average 1990-97 county yields for up to 3 of the base years) and 85 percent of base-period acres (payment acres) planted to peanuts (with provisions for prevented plantings). These payments are made regardless of current prices or the actual crop planted, so long as the farm remains in approved agricultural uses.

Producers with base acreage are also eligible to receive a counter-cyclical payment (CCP) when market prices are below an established target price of $495 per ton minus the $36 per ton direct payment. These payments are not related to current production, so long as the farm remains in approved agricultural uses. The payment rate is the difference between the target price and the "effective price," calculated as follows:

Payment rate = (target price) - (direct payment rate) - (higher of peanut market price or loan rate)

The total counter-cyclical payment to each eligible producer equals the product of the payment acres (85 percent of base acres), the program payment yield, and the specified payment rate:

CCP = 0.85 x (base acres) x (payment yield) x (payment rate).

Owners of peanut quota under prior legislation will receive a quota buy-out as compensation for the loss of quota asset value. Payments may be made in five annual installments of $0.11 per pound ($220 per short ton) during fiscal years 2002-06, or the quota owner may opt to take the outstanding payment due in a lump sum. Buy-out payments are based on the quota owner's 2001 quota, regardless of temporary leases or transfers of quota, so long as the person owned a farm eligible for the peanut quota. Continued eligibility for compensatory payments remains with the established quota owner regardless of future interest in the farm or whether the person continues to produce peanuts.

Economic implications
Production incentives created by the new programs will vary among different types of producers. Broadly speaking, those producers who primarily produced quota peanuts (those marketed for domestic edible consumption) will likely face lower prices for their peanuts, but they will receive quota buy-out, direct, and (depending on market prices) counter-cyclical payments. Production incentives for these producers will now be guided by the higher of market prices or the new $355 per ton loan rate, rather than by the old $610 per ton quota loan rate. Producers whose variable costs of peanut production exceed market prices plus any marketing loan benefits would be expected to switch to other crops or idle the land.

A second broad group of producers would be those who were previously growing additional peanuts. These producers were likely receiving an export or domestic crush price higher than the additional loan rate and probably will be able to cover their variable production costs. To the extent that domestic market prices or the new peanut loan rate exceeds prices they received under the previous system, these producers would likely to increase production. Revenues for these producers would also be augmented by direct payments and potential (depending on market prices) CCPs, since they also have a production history. Similarly, producers who previously rented quota rights from quota-holders may maintain some peanut production, if market prices or the peanut loan rate exceed their variable costs (which would no longer include a rental fee for the right to sell quota peanuts).

A third group would be new producers with no history of peanut production. The new legislation may result in these producers switching to peanuts if they perceive market prices plus marketing assistance loan benefits as resulting in higher net returns compared with other crops. Some of these producers may also receive direct and (depending on market prices) counter-cyclical payments on other crops for which they have established base acreage.

As with other program crops, direct support payments and counter-cyclical payments to peanut producers are contingent on historical acreage but not on current production, while marketing loan provisions are linked to current production. Analysis of marketing loans for other crops indicates that the program can create incentives to maintain production at a level higher than would occur in the absence of the program, and that relative loan rates between crops can be an important determinant of cropping patterns when prices are below loan rates. Decoupled (direct) payments create minimal incentives to increase production. (See U.S. Farm Program Benefits: Links to Planting Decisions and Agricultural Markets.)

The basis for the distribution of CCP benefits may affect producers' expectations of how future benefits will be dispersed. Payments that are linked to past production may lead to expectations that benefits in the future will be linked to now-current production. Such expectations can thereby affect current production decisions. Since CCPs are based on current market prices, producers may view the payments as an income hedge when electing to produce peanuts.

For more information...

 


for more information, contact: Edwin Young or Erik Dohlman
web administration: webadmin@ers.usda.gov
page updated: November 6, 2002

 

Key Topics Image
Shortcuts Image

USDA / FedStats / accessibility / privacy policy / contact us / advanced search