Back to National Journal
19 of 36 results     Previous Story  | Next Story  | Back to Results List

03-17-2001

POLITICS: Oops!

Would this damn airplane ever get off the ground? On a recent drizzly
Friday afternoon, Delta Air Lines overloaded the plane with cargo (to make
a few extra bucks) and a full complement of passengers and fuel. The
additional weight, coupled with the (predicted) rain, made the plane too
heavy to fly. More than an hour later, the standby passengers were ushered
off, and the plane finally left the runway at National Airport. This meant
that your travel-weary correspondent and his family missed their
connection to Tampa, spent the night at an airport hotel in Atlanta, and
arrived a day late-shorn of good spirits and several dollars-to celebrate
his sainted mother's 80th birthday.

So, is this how airline deregulation was supposed to work?

Well, yeah.

Ask the architect of the 1978 removal of federal controls over the airlines. Alfred E. Kahn was the chairman of the Civil Aeronautics Board and later an economic adviser to President Carter, and is now a professor emeritus of economics at Cornell University. The point of letting airlines decide on their own operations and fares, he explained in an interview, was to put air travel within everyone's reach-to provide "low-fare travel that would be uncomfortable. And boy, did we succeed." The endemic congestion at airports and the coach seating designed for dwarfs are "signs of success," said the wry Kahn, "not failure."

But something else has happened, he went on, that the deregulators never intended: The airline industry is consolidating into a few giants. "The present mergers are very frightening," he said, referring to the proposed amalgamations of American Airlines with TWA, and United Airlines with US Airways. After a multitude of mergers, and the disappearance of some of the industry's proudest names, these proposed consolidations would leave two U.S. airlines with half of the domestic business. And they would create the prospect of four or five airlines claiming more than 85 percent of the business, leaving the balance to a bunch of pip-squeaks with market shares that-as Kahn put it-"add up to peanuts." It is easy to start an airline, and many people have. But because of the industry's economies of scale and the restrictions on landing rights at popular airports, most of the born-yesterday airlines have collapsed or been taken over by larger competitors.

That airline deregulation would lead to fewer-not more-competitors, was "the furthest thing from [anyone's] mind," said Gene Kimmelman, the co-director of the Washington office of Consumers Union.

But this sort of thing happens all the time: Policy-makers set out to do something in particular, and they wind up doing something else entirely. Or, they accomplish the goal they intended and do something else they never imagined-whether they are happy about it or (more likely) aren't. Cocky policy wonks like to call this the "Law of Unintended Consequences," but it actually is nothing so predictable or certain. That our complicated world changes in wondrously unknowable ways is less like a law and more like a confluence of probabilities. So, the politicians and bureaucrats who try to predict-and alter-the course of events are bound to screw up.

When policy-makers try to deal with complex problems, unintended consequences are "absolutely inevitable," said Daniel Kahneman, a professor of psychology at Princeton University. He is considered the father of heuristics, the study of the art of mental shortcuts, which is grounded on the premise that the world is so complicated that no one can figure it out completely. Things change quickly, after all, and available facts are limited. "In addition," Kahneman appended, "we're not so smart."

Consider how policy typically gets made. Experts squabble, interest groups lobby, and staff members horse-trade. Then politicians, who may or may not know all of the ins and outs of what they're doing, work out an awkward compromise that keeps a majority of their constituencies barely content.

In 1996, not a single California lawmaker dissented when-intending to bring electricity prices down-the Legislature voted to end the state's regulation of electric power production. Only-they severely underestimated future demand; assumed, wrongly, that new competitors would enter the market; didn't bother to insist that electricity producers sell at agreed-upon prices for a number of years; failed to foresee that nearby states would compete for power; and didn't anticipate that out-of-state suppliers could withhold electricity from the market and thereby drive prices higher. As a result, average electricity prices in California more than tripled in a year, and a once-reliable power supply now relies on rolling blackouts to make ends meet. California's painful experience, in turn, has produced yet another unintended consequence: Municipalities around the state (and elsewhere) may shun deregulation and instead start their own, government-run power companies.

The grander the ambition, it seems, the greater the risk of something going awry. "When the government is doing something big, it is very often something difficult," said Charles L. Schultze, a former White House budget director and Council of Economic Advisers chairman. "You just can't figure out what the consequences are going to be."

Even actions that look routine at the time can wreak havoc. When President Clinton signed the Violence Against Women Act in 1994, he couldn't have imagined that four years later it would lead to his impeachment because it gave Paula Jones, who accused him of sexual harassment, the right to delve into his sex life. An election official in Palm Beach County, Fla., designed a "butterfly ballot" with larger type that was meant to make it easier for elderly voters to choose their preferred presidential candidate; it had the opposite effect, and might well have reversed the outcome of the 2000 election.

And now the victor's Administration is plotting out its own intended policy changes. If President George W. Bush succeeds in persuading Congress to cut income tax rates across the board, economist Henry Aaron at the Brookings Institution pointed out, it's possible-though not necessarily probable-that this will cause the budget surplus to vanish, interest rates to spike, and capital investment to contract, so that "productivity growth goes to hell." Which isn't at all what Bush intends. And the President's desire to repeal the estate tax has prompted some of the nation's richest folks (who stand to gain the most) to oppose the idea, partly because of the damage they say it would do to the level of charitable donations. As for privatizing part of Social Security, "God knows what that could lead to," said Schultze.

It's no surprise that First Amendment purists object to Bush's proposal to let religious institutions take federal money to run social-service programs. More startling are the objections from religious conservatives who are worried about the possible unintended consequences of bringing houses of worship under the government's purview. Televangelist Pat Robertson recently cautioned his viewers nationwide that the move could open "a real Pandora's box," in providing the likes of Hare Krishnas or the Church of Scientology with federal financial support. Marvin H. Kosters, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, said he is in favor of Bush's faith-based initiative, but he worries that the government's involvement in, say, a church's drug rehabilitation program could undermine its explicitly religious approach-the very element that may account for the program's success.

The notion that whatever government does is pretty much a shot in the dark need not lead to paralysis. It might argue, though, for caution and-as Bush's father liked to say-prudence. Yes, and "a certain amount of humility," added Steven M. Gillon, a historian at the University of Oklahoma and the author of a book published last year on unintended consequences of 20th-century American reforms. Humility is a quality the new President talks about a lot, though how seriously he practices it in his policy-making isn't obvious yet.

"You've got to be more careful," said Robert Pitofsky, the chairman of the Federal Trade Commission, in an interview. "You need to know things that engineers and biologists tend to know, but that legislators and government officials don't."

There are many reasons why policy doesn't play out according to plan, ranging from willful ignorance by policy-makers, to deviousness by the people they govern, to the labyrinthine nature of a world far beyond the understanding of mortals, even ones equipped with powerful computers. Prudent policy-making entails seeing around corners. And time and again, policy-makers can't-or won't. In the fashioning of laws, regulatory policy, and bureaucratic practice, the examples are legion, and maddeningly so. Here are just a few.

Creatures Sinful and Weak

Occasionally, a politician glimpses the hell that lies ahead. When President Johnson signed the landmark civil rights law of 1964, he famously-and accurately-predicted to an aide that, as a result, the Democrats would lose the South for a generation. The consequence may have been unintended, but it wasn't a surprise.

Sometimes, consequences do come as a surprise when, at least in retrospect, they probably shouldn't have. The advocates of virtue who brought us Prohibition in 1920 should not have been shocked that people would nevertheless continue to consume liquor, and that criminals would organize to supply it. Why didn't the authors of the 1982 law that deregulated savings and loan associations foresee the possibility that highfliers in the stodgy industry might invest flamboyantly in racehorses, casinos, and fast-food joints, leaving a trail of bankruptcies and bailouts? The Pentagon's attempt a couple of years ago to alleviate a shortage of military pilots by offering them bonuses of more than $100,000 caused dissension in the cockpits, with navigators and other crew members feeling shortchanged.

"The most important reason we have unintended consequences," Gillon pointed out, "is because we're human beings."

It seems to be a common mistake: to assume that human beings will behave nobly in situations where, too often, they don't. At times, the prospect that people can be weak, stupid, or selfish manifests itself guilelessly, even unconsciously. The use of safety belts in automobiles, some scholars say, prompts drivers to increase their speed, because the belts lower the risk to an acceptable level. W. Kip Viscusi, a professor of law and economics at Harvard Law School, has found that the use of "child-proof" caps on medicine bottles hasn't reduced the number of child poisonings. Parents "were lulled into a false sense of security" by the caps, he reported, so that they became less careful with medicines of all sorts. Poisonings from containers with safety caps didn't go down, and poisonings from medicines without them went up.

Looking for Loopholes

Sometimes, our failure to behave as the policy-makers expect us to isn't inadvertent. The human brain is endlessly inventive, especially when money is at stake. Last spring, legislators in Arizona had a nifty idea: Why not reduce air pollution over Phoenix and wean consumers away from gasoline-powered cars by offering a generous tax break for people who buy vehicles that can run on something else? Without a lot of debate or publicity, the state Legislature decreed that Arizonans who outfitted a new or existing vehicle with a separate tank for, say, propane or compressed natural gas could be reimbursed for the cost of the tank, plus 30 percent of the vehicle's overall worth. The resulting loophole was big enough to drive an SUV through. People could buy a pricey, gas-guzzling vehicle, put on a separate tank-but never use it-and get the state to pay for as much as half of the vehicle's cost. A subsidy that was expected to cost the state no more than $10 million a year soaked up at least a half-billion dollars. "Welfare for the well-to-do," a conservative editorialist grumbled. And the politicians who approved the idea paid a price: The state speaker lost his legislative seat, and the governor was widely criticized for her ham-handed reaction.

It isn't only ordinary citizens, of course, who are learned at finding loopholes. FTC Chairman Pitofsky recalled, for instance, that the Supreme Court's aggressiveness under Chief Justice Earl Warren in forbidding horizontal mergers (that captured as little as 5 percent to 6 percent of the market), prompted monopoly-minded companies to integrate vertically instead. Legions of lawyers are well-paid to find ways around what policy-makers intend. Indeed, Kahneman suggests that the government should hire top-flight lawyers of its own to look for loopholes in proposed legislation, before hired guns get their chance.

Because, if loopholes can be found, surely they will be, if the stakes are high enough. Take the quarter-century, unsuccessful battle to clean up the financing of political campaigns. The 1974 post-Watergate law that established strict limits on fund raising was meant to limit the role of money in politics and to accord challengers an equal chance against incumbents. "Neither happened," said David Boaz, the executive vice president of the libertarian Cato Institute. Instead, he recounted, the landmark law "turned out to be an incumbency-protection act, unintended or not."

Election cycle after election cycle, desperate candidates and fund-raisers-and lawyers-have seized on the tiniest cracks in legislative language, and the most generous interpretations of policy minutiae, to find innovative ways to funnel more money into political campaigns. Consider the saga of "soft money." Under the terms of the 1974 law, the sole means by which corporations or labor unions can make political donations is by contributing to "party-building," though only in the most literal sense-in the "construction or purchase" of a party headquarters. But that provision wasn't what opened the floodgates to the unlimited funds that corporations and labor unions have been giving in ever-increasing amounts to finance party-building of a less tangible sort. It was, rather, a 4-2 ruling by the Federal Election Commission in 1978 that permitted the Kansas Republican Party to raise this unregulated money to register new voters and get them to the polls, even if doing so affected a federal election.

Was this little-noticed decision a reasonable one at the time? "Yes, absolutely," according to Trevor Potter, a Republican lawyer who was on the commission from 1991-95. Yet, at the time, a Democratic dissenter warned that once the commission began letting politicians spend unregulated money, there would be no place to stop. That fear proved to be prescient. Soon, the FEC gave the same permission to national political parties that wished to help out their state affiliates, and then Michael S. Dukakis' Democratic presidential strategists in 1988 pioneered the use of soft money in a federal campaign. Bill Clinton raised the ante by using soft money to pay for televised issue ads in his 1996 re-election campaign.

Never intended as a major shift in policy, the soft-money provision has vitiated the nation's election laws. "People got cleverer and greedier," Potter explained, "and the regulatory system didn't respond."

But the prospect of legislation to outlaw soft money threatens some unintended consequences of its own. Democratic lawmakers who have opposed soft money-even as they've benefited from it-are now reportedly fearful that actually abolishing it would leave Republicans with an intolerable financial advantage.

Perverse Incentives

In 1956, the federal government began to offer sewer-and-water-pollution grants to local governments, in the hope of encouraging them to build water-treatment plants. But the program had the opposite effect. Year after year, Congress appropriated less money than the grants required, yet local officials remained ever-optimistic that more money would show up the next year. So they kept waiting to reapply for the grants yet again, rather than moving ahead on their own to build treatment plants, as they would have if the federal government had never stepped in.

"Public policy sets up different sets of incentives," said Michael W. Sherraden, a professor of social work at Washington University in St. Louis. "A lot of times, they're not thought through."

For many years, it was the practice of federal procurement officers not to take into account the past performance of companies that had sold stuff to the government before deciding whether to buy from them again. The rationale behind this approach was to prevent bureaucrats from exercising subjective judgment, and maybe showing favoritism-a suspicion that arose out of the public's growing distrust of government. But the result was-well, it isn't hard to guess. "It screwed up the incentives," said Steven Kelman, who oversaw the government's procurement system during Clinton's first term. Because there were no penalties for contractors with a history of performing poorly, he recalled, "there was no incentive" for them to try hard to do a good job.

Think of the incentives-or disincentives-that bedeviled the nation's welfare system for decades. Welfare helped millions of families get on their feet, but it also fostered a hand-me-down dependence and-because it was available for so many years only to single-parent families-made it economically rational for fathers to skedaddle or hide. Scholars dispute the importance of these disincentives, said AEI's Kosters, but "it is not disputed that there is an effect.... It is the biggest and most damaging unintended effect that I can think of."

Perverse incentives lurk everywhere. Why should anyone be surprised if the rising importance of standardized tests in schools has prompted administrators to cheat by, for example, categorizing slower kids as special-education students so that their scores don't bring down their school's total? Michael Maren, the author of The Road to Hell: The Ravaging Effects of Foreign Aid and International Charity, has argued that the humanitarian act of sending food to both sides in war-torn Sudan has given the combatants an instrument for solidifying their positions in the areas of the country they control, and has thus prolonged the fighting.

The wrong incentives can also be found in the pine forests along the U.S. coastline from East Texas to southern Virginia, the vanishing habitat of an endangered bird. Red-cockaded woodpeckers, named for the red tufts on the cheeks of the males, nest inside the trunks of longleaf pines-usually in trees at least 60 years old, with squishy-enough centers that an eight-inch bird can peck out a home. The pines don't reach their top price for lumber until they are 80 years old, but forestry consultants have advised landowners to cut down their trees decades earlier, before the woodpeckers move in. Because once they do, the Endangered Species Act decrees that the trees must be left standing for a half-mile around, and without governmental compensation for the landowner.

"Small landowners get panicky," said R.J. Smith, an environmental scholar at the Competitive Enterprise Institute, a market-oriented think tank in Washington. "You'd have to be crazy to bring woodpeckers onto your land."

"That was the problem with the Endangered Species Act-it promoted fear," said Ralph Costa, the recovery coordinator for red-cockaded woodpeckers at the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service. At Environmental Defense, an advocacy group, attorney Michael J. Bean acknowledged "instances" in which the law has been a disincentive. It isn't so much that landowners have destroyed the woodpeckers' habitat, he said, as that they have refrained from taking steps to improve it. He also pointed to another governmental attempt at environmental compassion that has hurt the endangered birds: The longtime practice (since abandoned) of suppressing forest fires on federal lands might have been a godsend for Smokey the Bear, but the denser forests made it harder for red-cockaded woodpeckers to thrive.

No Free Lunch

When Californians debated in 1978 whether to slash their property taxes by passing Proposition 13, opponents warned that it would injure the state's high-quality public schools. Either the voters didn't believe it or, given their financial pressures, they didn't care. The ballot initiative was approved, and the opponents turned out to be right.

Sometimes the public or the policy-makers want something so badly that they willfully-or unthinkingly-ignore the likely downsides and the necessary trade-offs. Examples abound. Out of concern for the privacy of children so poor that they qualify for subsidized school lunches, the authorities refrained from also offering them subsidized health insurance. Economic sanctions imposed by Washington on Cuba and Iraq haven't toppled any tyrants from power, but they have made life harder for the masses of people that the sanctions are meant to help. Fuel-efficiency standards intended to reduce U.S. reliance on foreign oil encouraged the popularity of smaller cars, which are estimated to have caused an extra 2,000 traffic fatalities each year. The fuel standards also sent jobs abroad by stoking the rise of Japanese automakers who were turning out the small, efficient cars at a time when Detroit was not. The potential difficulty in firing disabled workers because of the protections in the Americans With Disabilities Act may, in fact, discourage companies from hiring them in the first place.

Even populist symbolism can come at a price. Remember who got hurt by the luxury tax imposed on yachts and other play toys of the rich in 1990 to make former President Bush's deficit-cutting deal politically more palatable? The levy of 10 percent on the price of boats costing more than $100,000 wound up devastating the sales of new yachts, putting 100,000 less-than-wealthy workers (a sixth of the industry's workforce) out of jobs. "Chalk this up as a costly, painful example of the Law of Unintended Consequences," the Fort Lauderdale, Fla., Sun-Sentinel editorialized in 1993, once the tax was repealed, "and vow that it will never happen again."

But it did. When the federal government began to insist on passive restraints-in practice, air bags-in every new vehicle sold, the point was to save lives, not to take them. Concerns were raised about the impact of air bags on children seated "out of position," said Diane Steed, who headed the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration from 1983-89, but "I don't think anybody had any idea" of the danger posed to children and small women who sat in the right place. Air bags had been subjected to "very little" on-road experience, said Steed. As of last October, air bags had saved 6,138 lives-but killed 169 people, including 100 children and 67 women.

As Time Goes By

Usually, if you wait long enough, things change. When the Founding Fathers put the Second Amendment into the Bill of Rights to ensure "the right of the people to keep and bear arms," and thus assure "the security of a free State," could they have imagined the profusion of firearms that would someday turn mean streets into free-fire zones?

Or in more-upscale neighborhoods, the alternative minimum tax was intended, when it was enacted in 1969, to target the very rich who pay very little income tax because they shelter most of what they earn. But the levy is starting to hit middle-income households. The 1 million taxpayers now subject to the tax will expand to 17 million within a decade, said Frank Sammartino, an expert on taxes at the Urban Institute-and could go as high as 25 million, if Congress passes Bush's proposed tax cut. Over time, said Sammartino, the alternative minimum tax will fall on taxpayers who have lots of dependents, or who happen to reside in high-tax states. (See NJ, 2/24/01,

p. 574.)

A more spectacular instance of public policy that was ruined by the passage of time imploded in Baltimore last month, when the city razed its last standing example of high-rise public housing. Back in the 1950s and `60s, as slum housing gave way to urban renewal, apartment towers for the poor became the rage. The French architect known as Le Corbusier, with his predilection for boxy, industrial designs, was in vogue, and high-rises allowed the same density of development as the slums, yet with more open space.

But, even a Soviet architect who once toured high-rise housing in Chicago said it was "terrible-he would never do this," recalled Wayne Sherwood, a former public housing official who is a research consultant on low-income housing in Takoma Park, Md. And sure enough, the high-rises became places of rampant crime, dangerous drugs, and frightful anonymity. But the decline wasn't necessarily the result of an inherently flawed design, said Sherwood, so much as the reflection of a shift in the tenants. Increasingly, "working people didn't need public housing anymore," he explained, and the high-rises became home to single-parent, disastrously poor families.

"Mostly," Sherwood concluded, "the world changed."

An Intricate World

The world is so complicated that the most powerful computers can't accurately predict whether tomorrow morning will bring a light sprinkling of snow or the worst storm in a half-century. And the weather is the product of a closed physical system. So, what are the odds of prophecy when 6 billion people and at least as many interactions and imponderables are thrown into the mix?

"Everything is connected to everything," said economist Aaron. "There are always offshoot consequences."

Think of the vast consequences of policies that were begun for other purposes. When the government's wage and price controls during World War II left businesses scrounging for ways to attract workers, companies started to offer health insurance as a permissible come-on; from this recruitment tool evolved our national practice of relying on employers as the main vehicle for health coverage, which has left so many Americans uninsured and has discouraged self-employment. In the 1950s, the construction of the interstate highways smoothed the movement of goods and people, as its planners intended. But the planners never foresaw how this would lead to the proliferation of suburbs, beltways, and shopping malls-and transform the way most Americans live.

Details of policy that were barely noticed at the time have turned out to matter a lot. When members of Congress debated a higher-education bill in 1972, not much attention was paid to the promise of gender equality in Title IX, and even less to the impact it might make on college sports; and it was never imagined that the law would lead to decisions on some campuses to eliminate men's sports teams in order to make room for more women's teams. When lawmakers argued about tax reform in 1986, the subject of the horse-racing industry never came up, but the law wound up devastating the supply of racehorses.

Legislators who are thinking about one set of circumstances may prescribe rules that won't work in another situation. In 1980, when Congress passed the Superfund law as a mechanism to finance the cleanup of toxic-waste sites, it wrote liability rules specifying that any company that owned a Superfund site would be subject to "joint and several"-that is, possibly full-liability for any toxic wastes that might be found on it. The point was to deter future polluters. But the law also scared away companies that might want to purchase a site and clean it up enough to put up a factory and provide some jobs. A former Environmental Protection Agency official estimated that the liability provisions damaged the prospects for cleanup at "hundreds" of the agency's 1,400 listed Superfund sites.

But really, how could anyone have known? The crisis of the moment-the one that prompted all the lawmaking-involved a housing development in Niagara Falls, N.Y., called Love Canal. Its inhabitants had been forced to abandon their homes, and it was unimaginable that anyone would ever want to buy the place.

It's a wonder, in fact, that policy-makers ever get anything right. "There are complex sequences of events that usually can't be deduced from theory or intuition," said former Clinton domestic policy adviser William A. Galston, who is a public policy professor at the University of Maryland. "Knowing in advance that you can't know in advance is the beginning of wisdom in social policy."

Serendipity

Even in this glass-half-empty universe of policy prognostication, surprises needn't always be unhappy ones. Isabel V. Sawhill is a senior fellow at Brookings who was a senior White House budget official early in Clinton's tenure. She remembers how unshakable the inherited budget deficit seemed to be, as she scrounged for possible cuts in federal spending. "Never in our wildest dreams," she said, even amid the drama of the Administration's triumph in battling the deficit in 1993, did the policy-makers imagine the surpluses that have become a political fact of life.

On occasion, a significant change at one place on the chain of supply can bring magnified improvements at another. When the federal government lifted controls from the trucking industry in 1980, economists figured that market-driven efficiencies (such as truckers no longer having to drive rigs home empty) would save consumers up to $8 billion a year. But a 1987 study by Cato found benefits 10 times as large. What happened? Boaz said that "no one anticipated the huge reductions in inventories" that were possible once manufacturers of all sorts gained confidence that an available truck could always be found to bring them new supplies. This encouraged the now-standard system of just-in-time inventory.

Pleasant surprises range from the cosmic to the trivial. Back in the 1960s, the Pentagon's R&D agency set out to build a flexibly configured communications network, with computer software that allowed messages to reach their destination even if particular nodes had been destroyed, say, in a nuclear attack. After university researchers adapted the system, to keep in touch with one another, it quickly evolved into the Internet.

And when the 1990 Americans With Disabilities Act required local governments to put in curb cuts at street corners, to accommodate wheelchairs, the ramps weren't regarded as a boon to skateboarders, or bicyclists, or parents with strollers. But that's what they are.

Fixing Mistakes

Far-sighted, dispassionate people don't make laws. Politicians do. And they don't do so in a far-sighted, dispassionate way. In legislatures, in bureaucracies, and even in the judiciary, decision-makers spend most of their professional hours between a rock and a hard place. Unwieldy compromises and delicate balances count as successes.

Yet, the same haphazard political processes that can yield an irrational outcome can also be used to fix mistakes. A 1994 law that overhauled federal procurement practices included language that authorized the government's buyers to take into account a bidder's previous performance record. The policy "was easier to change than I thought it would be," said former procurement chief Kelman, who is now a professor of public management at Harvard University's John F. Kennedy School of Government.

Last June, President Clinton signed a bill that lets local school administrators tell federal health officials about poor children who receive subsidized lunches and who might qualify for medical coverage. A few years ago, the liability scheme at Superfund sites was made more enticing, when the EPA began to offer potential purchasers contracts that excuse them from liability for pollution that wasn't their doing; 125 have been signed so far. The Fish and Wildlife Service has tried to encourage a home for red-cockaded woodpeckers by promising not to impose restrictions on landowners if they improve their pine forests and the woodpeckers return. "It's just common sense-why should we punish landowners who want to help?" said the agency's Costa. So far, more than 100 of the private landowners have struck deals with the feds, covering nearly half of the woodpeckers that live on privately held lands.

Sometimes, properly repairing an unintended consequence takes a couple of whacks. The 1997 budget-balancing law, in trying to prune federal spending on health care for the elderly, overdid it. Instead of cutting the 1998-2002 payments to hospitals and other medical facilities by $115 billion, as they intended, lawmakers wound up chopping Medicare reimbursements by $227 billion, because of unforeseen trends in health care and in the overall economy. So Congress then tried to fix the resulting mess-twice. A reimbursement bill in 1999 proved to be too modest, so another one was enacted in 2000.

So how can a policy-maker anticipate-and avoid-consequences that aren't intended? "You can't," sighed Kahn, on the phone from Ithaca, N.Y., where the airline service is far spottier than it was before deregulation. "You do the best you can."

Burt Solomon National Journal
- Advertisement -

- Advertisement -
Need A Reprint Of This Article?
National Journal Group offers both print and electronic reprint services, as well as permissions for academic use, photocopying and republication. Click here to order, or call us at 202-266-7230.

19 of 36 results     Previous Story  | Next Story  | Back to Results List