Home > Renewables > Renewable Fuels Publications > Renewable Energy 2000 - Issues and Trends > Incentives |
Report Date: February 2001 Next Release Date: None Incentives, Mandates, and
|
Table 1. Timeline - Major Tax Provisions Affecting Renewable Energy | |
---|---|
1978 | Energy Tax Act of 1978 (ETA) (P.L.95-618)
Residential energy (income) tax credits for solar and wind energy equipment expenditures: 30 percent of the first $2,000 and 20 percent of the next $8,000. Business energy tax credit: 10 percent for investments in solar, wind, geothermal, and ocean thermal technologies; (in addition to standard 10 percent investment tax credit available on all types of equipment, except for property which also served as structural components, such as some types of solar collectors, e.g., roof panels). In sum, investors were eligible to receive income tax credits of up to 25 percent of the cost of the technology. Percentage depletion for geothermal deposits: depletion allowance rate of 22 percent for 1978-1980 and 15 percent after 1983. |
1980 | Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act of 1980 (WPT)
(P.L.96-223)
Increased the ETA residential energy tax credits for solar, wind, and geothermal technologies from 30 percent to 40 percent of the first $10,000 in expenditures. Increased the ETA business energy tax credit for solar, wind, geothermal, and ocean thermal technologies from 10 percent to 15 percent, and extended the credits from December 1982 to December 1985. Expanded and liberalized the tax credit for equipment that either converted biomass into a synthetic fuel, burned the synthetic fuel, or used the biomass as a fuel. Allowed tax-exempt interest on industrial development bonds for the development of solid waste to energy (WTE) producing facilities, for hydroelectric facilities, and for facilities for producing renewable energy. |
1981 | Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 (ERTA) (P.L.97-34)
Allowed accelerated depreciation of capital (five years for most renewable energy-related equipment), known as the Accelerated Cost Recovery System (ACRS); public utility property was not eligible. Provided for a 25 percent tax credit against the income tax for incremental expenditures on research and development (R&D). |
1982 | Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982
(TEFRA) (P.L.97-248)
Canceled further accelerations in ACRS mandated by ERTA, and provided for a basis adjustment provision which reduced the cost basis for purposes of ACRS by the full amount of any regular tax credits, energy tax credit, rehabilitation tax credit. |
1982-1985 | Termination of Energy Tax Credits
In December 1982, the 1978 ETA energy tax credits terminated for the following categories of non-renewable energy property: alternative energy property such as synfuels equipment and recycling equipment; equipment for producing gas from geopressurized brine; shale oil equipment; and cogeneration equipment. The remaining energy tax credits, extended by the WPT, terminated on December 31, 1985. |
1986 | Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L.99-514)
Repealed the standard 10 percent investment tax credit. Eliminated the tax-free status of municipal solid waste (MSW) powerplants (WTE) financed with industrial development bonds, reduced accelerated depreciation, and eliminated the 10 percent tax credit (P.L.96-223). Extended the WPT business energy tax credit for solar property through 1988 at the rates of 15 percent for 1986, 12 percent for 1987, and 10 percent for 1988; for geothermal property through 1988 at the rates of 15 percent for 1986, and 10 percent for 1987 and 1988; for ocean thermal property through 1988 at the rate of 15 percent; and for biomass property through 1987 at the rates of 15 percent for 1986, and 10 percent for 1987. (The business energy tax credit for wind systems was not extended and, consequently, expired on December 31, 1985.) Public utility property became eligible for accelerated depreciation. |
1992 | Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT) (P.L.102-486)
Established a permanent 10 percent business energy tax credit for investments in solar and geothermal equipment. Established a 10-year, 1.5 cents per kilowatthour (kWh) production tax credit (PTC) for privately owned as well as investor-owned wind projects and biomass plants using dedicated crops (closed-loop) brought on-line between 1994 and 1993, respectively, and June 30, 1999. Instituted the Renewable Energy Production Incentive (REPI), which provides 1.5 cents per kWh incentive, subject to annual congressional appropriations (section 1212), for generation from biomass (except municipal solid waste), geothermal (except dry steam), wind and solar from tax exempt publicly owned utilities and rural cooperatives. Indefinitely extended the 10 percent business energy tax credit for solar and geothermal projects. |
1999 | Tax Relief Extension Act of 1999 (P.L. 106-170)
Extends and modifies the production tax credit (PTC in EPACT) for electricity produced by wind and closed-loop biomass facilities. The tax credit is expanded to include poultry waste facilities, including those that are government-owned . All three types of facilities are qualified if placed in service before January 1, 2002. Poultry waste facilities must have been in service after 1999. A nonrefundable tax credit of 20 percent is available for incremental research expenses paid or incurred in a trade or business. |
Notes: The residential energy credit provided a credit (offset) against tax due for a portion of taxpayer expenditures for energy conservation and renewable energy sources. The general business credit is a limited nonrefundable credit (offset) against income tax that is claimed after all other nonrefundable credits. |
Table 2. Timeline - Major Tax Provisions Affecting Renewable Transportation Fuels | |
---|---|
1978 | Energy Tax Act of 1978 (ETA) (P.L.95-618)
Excise tax exemption through 1984 for alcohol fuels (methanol and ethanol): exemption of 4 cents per gallon (the full value of the excise tax at that time) of the Federal excise tax on "gasohol" (gasoline or other motor fuels that were at least 10 percent alcohol (methanol and ethanol)) |
1980 | Crude Oil Windfall Profits Tax Act of 1980 (WPT)
(P.L.96-223)
Extended the gasohol excise tax exemption from October 1, 1984, to December 31, 1992. Introduced the alternative fuels production tax credit. The credit of $3 per barrel equivalent is indexed to inflation using 1979 as the base year, and is applicable only if the real price of oil is bellow $27.50 per barrel. The credit is available for fuel produced and sold from facilities placed in service between 1979 and 1990. The fuel must be sold before 2001. Introduced the alcohol fuel blenders' tax credit; available to the blender in the case of blended fuels and to the user or retail seller in the case of straight alcohol fuels. This credit of 40 cents per gallon for alcohol of at least 190 proof and 45 cents per gallon for alcohol of at least 150 proof but less that 190 proof was available through December 31, 1992. Extended the ETA gasohol excise tax exemption through 1992. Tax-exempt interest on industrial development bonds for the development of alcohol fuels produced from biomass, solid waste to energy producing facilities, for hydroelectric facilities, and for facilities for producing renewable energy. |
1982 | Surface Transportation Assistance Act (STA) (P.L.
97-424)
Raised the gasoline excise tax from 4 cents per gallon to 9 cents per gallon, and increased the ETA gasohol excise tax exemption from 4 cents per gallon to 5 cents per gallon. Provided a full excise tax exemption of 9 cents per gallon for "neat" alcohol fuels (fuels having an 85 percent or higher alcohol content). |
1984 | Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 (P.L.98-369)
The STA excise tax exemption for gasohol was raised from 5 cents per gallon to 6 cents per gallon. Provided a new exemption of 4.5 cents per gallon for alcohol fuels derived from natural gas. The alcohol fuels "blenders" credit was increased from 40 cents to 60 cents per gallon of blend for 190 proof alcohol. The duty on alcohol imported for use as a fuel was increased from 50 cents to 60 cents per gallon |
1986 | Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L.99-514)
Reduced the tax exemption for "neat" alcohol fuels (at least 85 percent alcohol) from 9 cents to 6 cents per gallon. Permitted alcohol imported from certain Caribbean countries to enter free of the 60 cents per gallon duty. Repealed the tax-exempt financing provision for alcohol-producing facilities. |
1990 | Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 (P.L.
101-508)
Allows ethanol producers a 10 cent per gallon tax credit for up to 15 million gallons of ethanol produced annually. Reduced the STA gasohol excise tax exemption to 5.4 cents per gallon. |
1992 | Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT) (P.L. 102-486)
Provides: (1) a tax credit (variable by gross vehicle weight) for dedicated alcohol-fueled vehicles; (2) a limited tax credit for alcohol dual-fueled vehicles; and (3) a tax deduction for alcohol fuel dispensing equipment. |
1998 | Energy Conservation Reauthorization Act of 1998 (ECRA)
(P.L. 105-388)
Amended EPACT to include a credit program for biodiesel use by establishing Biodiesel Fuel Use Credits. An EPACT-covered fleet can receive one credit for each 450 gallons of neat (100 percent) biodiesel purchased for use in vehicles weighing in excess of 8500 lbs (gross vehicle weight (GVW)). One credit is equivalent to one alternative fueled vehicle (AFV) acquisition. To qualify for the credit, the biodiesel must be used in biodiesel blends containing at least 20 percent biodiesel (B20) by volume. If B20 is used, 2,250 gallons must be purchased to receive one credit. Transportation Equity Act for the 21st Century (TEA-21) (P.L. 105-178) Maintains, through 2000, the 5.4 cent per gallon (of gasoline) excise tax exemption for fuel ethanol set by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 (P.L. 101-508). Extends the benefits through September 30, 2007, and December 31, 2007, but cuts the ethanol excise tax exemption to 5.3, 5.2, and 5.1 cents for 2001-2002, 2003-2004, and 2005-2007, respectively, and the income tax credits by equivalent amounts. The exemption is eliminated entirely in 2008. |
However, only the partial exemption from motor fuels excise tax is used to any extent. It is important to note that there are important financial incentive issues in the form of tax equity regarding all of the "alternate transportation fuels." However, only the alcohol fuels are renewable, so this paper is confined to those. The primary incentive is the ethanol excise tax exemption.
Research and Development
Government research and development
(R&D), especially applied research, is considered a support program
because, when successful, it reduces the capital and/or operating costs of
new products or processes. Research and development comprises three
components: basic research (original investigation in some area but with
no specific commercial objective), applied research (investigation with a
specific commercial objective in mind), and development (translating
scientific discovery into commercial products or processes). (16)
Figure 1.
R&D Funding for Selected Renewable Energy
Technologies (1999 Dollars) |
![]() |
The Department of Energy (DOE) applied research program for renewable energy is accomplished through the use of partnership programs. These programs, in which the Department acts primarily as a facilitator, have been a prominent part of renewables R&D funding since the mid-1980s. There are two funding components to this type of program: cost-sharing and in-kind contributions. Cost sharing refers to project funding contributions by all parties involved in the project. In-kind contributions refer primarily to, on the company side, the payment of salaries and the use of equipment and resources during the course of work on the project, and on the government side, the use of capital equipment, such as scientific and engineering equipment and facilities at DOE's national laboratories. (In the past, such programs have included a payback feature where the contractor repaid the government its original investment once the project became commercial and profitable.) In partnering programs, the Department also works with the ultimate product consumer to determine desired product characteristics and feeds this information back to its partner(s). For R&D projects, the private sector cost share is 20 percent. By comparison, demonstration projects require at least a 50 percent cost share by private firms. Figure 1 shows renewable energy R&D funding over time in 1999 dollars.
The DOE has consistently supported solar (including solar thermal, passive solar, and photovoltaic) R&D efforts at a higher level than other renewables. However, major new Presidential biofuels energy initiatives during the past 2 years have increased 1999 DOE R&D spending for biomass energy systems (including both electric and transportation applications) by 64 percent over its 1997 level. In 1999, more than 35 percent of biomass energy system R&D was directed toward ethanol. (17) Major areas being investigated are: advanced fermentation organisms, advanced cellulase (enzyme) development, integrating the various stages of cellulose to ethanol production, and support for cellulose to ethanol demonstration production facilities. (18) The principal method for achieving production increases is via leveraged partnerships with private ethanol producers.
Other Federal agencies have also
contributed to renewable energy R&D efforts. The National Aeronautics
and Space Administration (NASA) works on fuel cell research (in
conjunction with DOE), solar energy applications in underdeveloped
countries, and conducts modest studies on microwave energy from solar
panels which would orbit the earth. The Department of Agriculture (USDA)
has the Alternative Agricultural Research and Commercialization
Corporation, a venture capital firm for alternate energy sources. USDA
also joins effort with the Environmental Protection Agency to capture
methane from lagoons to supply heat and power.
Electric industry restructuring is the major issue affecting renewable energy at the State levels. In a few States, electric industry restructuring legislation supports renewable energy with financial incentives through funds from surcharges on electricity sales or renewable portfolio standards. (19) Most States provide for net metering. (20) Even prior to electric restructuring legislation, many States had financial incentives for renewable energy. (A DOE-sponsored North Carolina State University website provides summary information, updated periodically, on State-level financial incentives, and regulatory programs and policies for renewable energy.) (21)
State financial incentives include personal income tax credits and deductions for the purchase of various renewable-based technologies or alternative fuel vehicles; corporate income tax credits, exemptions, and deductions for investments in renewable technologies; sales tax exemptions on renewable equipment purchases; variable property tax exemptions on the value added by the renewable energy system; renewable technology and demonstration project grants; and special loan programs for renewable energy investments.
Some State incentives for renewable energy technologies overlap the Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT) Production Tax Credit (PTC). When State and Federal incentives overlap, the PTC may or may not be reduced, depending on Internal Revenue Service rulings. In California, for example, wind projects canget renewable resource funds without jeopardizing eligibility for the PTC. In other cases, the PTC is reduced by the amount of the State incentive. (22)
While some ethanol-producing States do not subsidize ethanol, others offer tax incentives for gasoline blended with ethanol and for ethanol production, which vary from $0.10 to $0.40 per gallon.
Because of its long history of promoting renewable energy and the dominant position which the State holds in renewable energy production, (23) this report examines renewable energy incentives promulgated by California. From about 1980 through 1983, California had a 25-percent tax credit for wind energy systems. Combined with Federal tax credits, the effective tax credit for wind plants during that time was nearly 50 percent. It is therefore hardly surprising that wind energy capacity in California grew from 176 MW in 1982 to 1,015 MW in 1985. California also strongly supported renewables beginning in 1982 via pricing terms of the Standard Offer 4 contract mentioned earlier, which utilities were required to sign with qualifying facilities.
With the move toward deregulation and restructuring of the electric power industry, the California General Assembly passed a law in 1996, which on March 31, 1998, opened electricity markets to retail competition. Although California had previously been aggressive in promoting renewable energy, Assembly Bill (AB) 1890 enacted an entirely different approach. It established a new statewide renewables policy by providing $540 million collected from the State's three largest investor-owned utilities over 4 years starting in 1998 to support existing, new, and emerging renewable technologies to make the transition to a competitive market. The bill also allocates an additional $62.5 million for energy projects deemed to be in the "public interest."
After the California Energy Commission submitted its recommendations to the Legislature for allocating and distributing these funds ($540 million) in March 1997, the General Assembly enacted Senate Bill 90, which created a Renewable Resource Trust Fund containing four accounts: Existing Renewable Resources Account ($243 million), New Renewable Resources Account ($162 million), Emerging Renewable Resources Account ($54 million), and Customer-side Renewable Resources Account ($81million).
The program has a competitive bidding mechanism to reward the most cost-effective projects with a productionincentive for existing and new technologies. (24) The funds are distributed by program type as follows:
By early July 1998, the new technologies auction received 56 bids representing nearly 600 megawatts of new renewable energy resources. All of the bids received amounted to a total of $182 million in incentive payments, $20 million more than the $162 million allocated in the renewable energy program for new generation. Bids were used to ensure a competitive, market-based, environment using a performance-based criterion. They were submitted on a cents per kWh basis for electricity production, not to exceed 1.5 cents. The renewable resource technologies determined eligible to receive funding at an average incentive of 1.2 cents per kWh include: wind, approximately 300 megawatts (also eligible for the PTC); geothermal, 157 megawatts; landfill gas, 70 megawatts; biomass, 12 megawatts; digester gas, 1 megawatt; and small hydro, 1 megawatt. The combined impact of all incentives (State and Federal) has assisted in bringing 290 MW of new or repowered wind capacity online in 1999. (25) Thus, the incentives used in California have been successful in meeting the objective of increasing the number of renewable projects in the State.
A major characteristic responsible for this success is the incentive program's competitive bidding mechanism to reward the most cost-effective projects, using a production incentive rather than an investment tax credit.
Public Interest Energy Research Program (PIER) - Assembly Bill 1890 also requires that a minimum of $62.5 million in funds, collected annually from investor-owned utility ratepayers, be used for "public interest" energy research development and demonstration (RD&D) efforts that would not be provided adequately by either a competitive or regulated market. Senate Bill 90 required that the PIER portfolio include the following areas: renewable energy technologies; environmentally preferred advanced generation; energy-related environmental enhancements; end-use energy efficiency; andstrategic energy research.
How effective have renewable energy incentives, mandates, and Federal and State programs been? It is virtually impossible to quantify the effect of any single action, because of the interdependence of many of the renewable energy programs in effect at any one time. Even the effects of straightforward incentives such as the Renewable Energy Production Incentives (REPI) are difficult to determine, because it is not known how much renewable generation would have been produced in the absence of REPI. Further, REPI itself may not have been sufficient to induce the renewable generation eligible for REPI payments, but rather a combination of REPI and other Federal and State incentives. Following is a discussion of the effectiveness of four Federal renewable energy support programs--PURPA, REPI, the Federal ethanol incentive program, and R&D funding. The characteristics of these programs and an assessment of whether they have proven effective in achieving the desired results are discussed.
PURPA
This assessment of the effectiveness of PURPA is actually an assessment of PURPA in combination with various tax incentives in place between 1978 and 1998. PURPA established a new class of generator, qualifying facilities (QF), that afforded cogenerators and certain renewable generators the opportunity to sell electricity to electric utilities at the utility's avoided cost rates. These facilities were also granted tax benefits described in Table 1, which lowered their overall costs.
PURPA's QF status applied to existing
as well as new projects. Together, by year-end 1998, existing and new
projects totaled 12,658 megawatts of QF renewable capacity (Table
3). Of this, two-thirds (8,219 megawatts) of QF capacity was biomass.
Some of these biomass QFs, however, were not "new" facilities, but rather
had gone into commercial operation prior to PURPA.
(26) PURPA enabled these facilities to connect to the grid, if
they chose to become QFs, and sell any generation beyond their own use at
avoided cost rates.
As stated in the Introduction, two of
the criteria for evaluating the effectiveness of incentives and mandates
such as PURPA are renewable capacity and generation growth. The EIA began
collecting data from nonutility companies in 1989 (Table
4), 11 years after the passage of PURPA. However, between 1989
and 1998, renewable capacity increased by 11.9 percent. At the national
level, non-hydroelectric renewable generating capacity rose by 4,426 MW;
the increase in hydroelectric capacity was 5,703 MW. Renewable generation
rose by 22 percent (Table
5). Most of the increase in electricity generation from renewable
energy is in the utility hydropower sector, including net imports. Nearly
all of the increase in biomass, geothermal, solar, and wind generation
occurred between 1989 and 1993. Non-hydro renewable generation, excluding
imports, actually declined by more than 5 percent between 1993 and 1998,
due primarily to California replacing Standard Offer 4 contract "avoided
cost" provisions with competitive bidding mechanisms, and declining
production at The Geysers geothermal plant. Also, in 1992, New York
amended its Six-Cent Rule, which established a 6-cents-per-kilowatthour
floor on avoided costs for projects less than 80 MW in size, such that it
was not applicable to any future power purchase agreements. (27)
Table 5. Electricity Generation From Renewable Energy by Energy Source, 1989-1998 (Thousand Kilowatthours) |
---|
![]() |
Data on
renewable capacity in California were available for years prior to 1989.
These data, for 1980 through 1996 (Table
6), more clearly show the growth in renewable capacity owned by
nonutilities since the passage of PURPA. Renewable-based nonutility
capacity (excluding cogeneration) rose from 187 megawatts in 1980 to 3,777
megawatts (excluding small hydropower and cogeneration plants) in 1996.
Table 6. California Nonutility Power Plants Installed Capacity, 1980-1996 (Megawatts) | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Year | Cogenerationa | Waste-to-Energyb | Geothermal | Small Hydro | Solar | Wind | Total |
1980 | 227 | 14 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 173 | 414 |
1981 | 261 | 14 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 176 | 451 |
1982 | 412 | 32 | 0 | 48 | 1 | 176 | 669 |
1983 | 658 | 46 | 9 | 59 | 8 | 227 | 1,007 |
1984 | 893 | 79 | 96 | 67 | 27 | 496 | 1,658 |
1985 | 1,444 | 140 | 178 | 107 | 57 | 1,015 | 2,941 |
1986 | 1,788 | 275 | 188 | 144 | 122 | 1,235 | 3,752 |
1987 | 3,063 | 396 | 319 | 176 | 155 | 1,366 | 5,475 |
1988 | 3,662 | 513 | 587 | 229 | 221 | 1,378 | 6,590 |
1989 | 4,942 | 783 | 806 | 298 | 301 | 1,382 | 8,512 |
1990 | 5,315 | 878 | 870 | 321 | 381 | 1,647 | 9,412 |
1991 | 5,838 | 883 | 813 | 330 | 374 | 1,698 | 9,936 |
1992 | 5,684 | 804 | 831 | 371 | 408 | 1,729 | 9,827 |
1993 | 5,778 | 845 | 863 | 370 | 373 | 1,797 | 10,026 |
1994 | 5,857 | 795 | 863 | 410 | 373 | 1,629 | 9,927 |
1995 | 6,280 | 709 | 846 | 349 | 368 | 1,630 | 10,182 |
1996 | 6,177 | 823 | 885 | 362 | 360 | 1,709 | 10,316 |
aIncludes gas-fired facilities
and biomass co-firing and
cogeneration. bWaste-to-Energy includes wood and wood waste, municipal solid waste, landfill gas, and other biomass. However, biomass co-firing and cogeneration capacity is included under cogeneration. Source: California Energy Commission, Draft Final Report, California Historical Energy Statistics, January 1998, Publication Number: P300-98-001. Notes: Data exlude facilities rated less than 5 megawatts. Some data in this table are inconsistent with national data in Table 4 due to different sources, categories, and coverage. Also, these data represent installed capacity, while the data in Table 4 represent net summer capability. |
Most of the growth had occurred by 1990. Between 1990 and 1993, California nonutility renewable capacity (excluding small hydropower and cogeneration plants) increased just 3 percent to 3,878 megawatts, and between 1993 and 1995, capacity actually dropped to 3,553 megawatts; generation followed a similar pattern. The principal reasons for this decline were the lower PURPA "avoided costs" when the long-term energy payment provisions of the contracts (usually 10-years), mostly signed in the early 1980s, expired. Natural gas prices in nominal dollars paid by electric utilities in California declines from a high of $6.77 per million Btu in 1982 to between $2.50 to $3.00 in 1986 through 1993. By 1995, the price declined further to $2.22. (28) This, along with the repeal of the standard investment tax credits in 1986, caused some wind, biomass, and solar facilities to reduce output or cease operation. (29) Also, there was a substantial slowdown in the construction of new capacity. This slowdown transpired despite substantial decreases in short-run average costs of renewables because the operation costs were not reduced enough to be competitive in the market conditions of the mid-to-late 1990s. (30)
Another criterion in evaluating the effectiveness of PURPA, in addition to expansion of renewable energy capacity and generation, is the cost competitiveness of the renewable facilities in the market. Utility wholesale power purchases from other utilities, which are more often made on a mutually agreeable economic basis between utilities and may be regarded as reflecting "wholesale" prices, averaged 3.53 cents per kWh nationwide in 1995. (31) Although EIA has not attempted to estimate the cost of PURPA directly, (32) it has examined the prices that utilities paid in 1995 to purchase power from nonutilities and, in particular, PURPA QF nonutilities using renewable resources. (33) The average price utilities paid all nonutilities was 6.31 cents per kWh nationwide, considerably higher than the average wholesale price. Higher still was the price utilities paid nonutilities for renewable-based electricity. Utilities paid an average of 8.78 cents per kWh for power generated from renewable sources, compared with 5.49 cents per kWh for power from non-renewable sources. (34) Utilities paid an average of 9.05 cents per kWh for nearly 42,800 million kWh of power from renewable QFs in 1995, compared with just 5.17 cents per kWh for 3,300 million kWh of power from non-QF renewables. This difference was even more extreme in California, where the renewable QF/non-QF purchased power costs were 12.79 and 3.33 cents per kWh, respectively. (35) All non-QF purchases of renewable energy, however, were from hydropower facilities, (36) the lowest cost renewable resource-and the lowest cost of all electricity resources. (37) In analyzing these data, the reader should bear in mind that by 1995, many of the original PURPA power purchase contracts between utilities and nonutilities had expired. Therefore, the data reflect a mixture of the original avoided cost contracts and newer contracts. (38)
Renewable-based generation costs would obviously have compared much more favorably with other generation costs during 2000, when California experienced severe electricity and natural gas shortages. Natural gas prices--the primary basis for determining alternative generation cost--rose sharply during 2000. Through September, the average cost of gas delivered to electric utilities in California increased to $4.32 per million Btu as compared to $2.68 for deliveries through September 1999. (39)
Renewable Energy Production Incentive (REPI)
Initial
payments under the Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPACT) Renewable Energy
Production Incentive (REPI, summarized in Table
1), for Fiscal Year (FY) 1994 totaled $693,120 and were distributed
among four State-owned and three city-owned facilities which generated 42
million kWh of electricity from seven facilities (Table
7). One used wind, two used solar photovoltaics (PV), and four used
methane from landfills.
(40) By FY 1998, net generation eligible for REPI payment had
reached 529 million kWh from 19 facilities. Interesting points to note
about the REPI program are: (1) The number of facilities has remained
relatively stable since FY 1996; (2) The number of solar/PV facilities has
been quite modest, except for a one-time increase in FY 1996 which did not
result in a sizable increase in REPI-eligible generation; and (3) The
greatest increase in both eligible facilities and generation occurred in
two areas, landfill methane and wood waste, which are often excluded
(along with municipal solid waste) from actual and proposed renewable
energy incentives; and (4) only tax-exempt facilities are
eligible.
Table 7. Renewable Energy Production Incentive (REPI) Disbursements | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Fiscal Year | Facilities | Energy Source | Net Generation (million kWh) |
Nominal Payments (thousand dollars) |
1994 | ||||
2 | Solar PV | 8 | ||
1 | Wind | 93 | ||
4 | Landfill Methane | 592 | ||
Total | 7 | 42 | 693 | |
1995 | ||||
4 | Solar PV | 15 | ||
2 | Wind | 205 | ||
5 | Landfill Methane | 2,178 | ||
Total | 11 | 153 | 2,398 | |
1996 | ||||
9 | Solar PV | 28 | ||
3 | Wind | 205 | ||
5 | Landfill Methane | 1,879 | ||
1 | Biomass Digester Gas | 417 | ||
Total | 18 | 177 | 2,529 | |
1997 | 2 | Solar PV | 31 | |
3 | Wind | 123 | ||
8 | Landfill Methane | 1,212 | ||
1 | Biomass Digester Gas | 265 | ||
1 | Wood Waste | 1,222 | ||
Total | 15 | 458 | 2,853 | |
1998 | ||||
3 | Solar PV | 91 | ||
5 | Wind | 31 | ||
9 | Landfill Methane | 1,716 | ||
1 | Biomass Digester Gas | 359 | ||
1 | Wood Waste | 1,803 | ||
Total | 19 | 529 | 4,000 | |
Source: http://www.eren.doe.gov/power/repi.html (October 22, 1999). |
It is important to note that while the generation eligible for REPI payments increased more than twelvefold, the number of facilities receiving REPI support increased only threefold, and that increase occurred during the first 3 years of the program. This could have occurred because the 1.5 cents per kWh has not been sufficient to encourage much additional construction, though it may be a factor in maintaining production from economically marginal wind farms, or, more likely, because of the uncertainty associated with year-to-year congressional appropriations, or both. For existing biomass generators, whose variable costs per kWh are generally higher than those for wind generators, the 1.5-cents-per-kWh credit is much less likely to support continued operation of marginal plants.
Federal Ethanol Incentive Program
Prior to the Federal ethanol subsidy program, begun in 1979, (41) the United States produced virtually no fuel ethanol. In the first year of the subsidy program, the United States produced 10 million gallons. Production increased rapidly, to 175 million gallons in 1981, 870 million gallons in 1990, 1.4 billion gallons in 1998, and 1.5 billion gallons in 1999. (42) Virtually all production is in the Midwest, and fuel ethanol stocks are sizable only in the Midwest and Gulf Coast regions.
To determine what production of ethanol would be without the subsidies, it is necessary to analyze ethanol's three distinct purposes as an additive to gasoline. Originally, it was used to extend gasoline supplies as "gasohol," a mixture of 10 percent ethanol and 90 percent gasoline. As such, it was necessary for ethanol to compete economically with gasoline, necessitating the 54-cent-per gallon subsidy of corn-based ethanol. Ethanol also is used to raise the octane level of gasoline--its octane rating is 133. Beginning in the late 1970s, the use of lead, the only major octane enhancer used until then, was phased down. Both MTBE (43) and ethanol were used.
For octane-enhancing purposes, MTBE has a clear economic advantage over ethanol. More recently, ethanol and MTBE have been added to gasoline as an oxygenate to reduce harmful emissions. The incremental cost per gallon of MTBE-based gasoline (which receives no subsidy) is 2 to 3 cents per gallon. Using a 7.7 percent blend of ethanol, the value of the ethanol subsidy alone in a gallon of gasoline would be 4.1 cents. The total incremental cost per gallon of ethanol-based gasoline is 4.4 cents. (44) While MTBE has an economic advantage per gallon of additive, ethanol has a higher oxygen content than MTBE. Thus, only about half the volume of ethanol is required to produce the same oxygen level in gasoline as if MTBE is used. This allows ethanol, typically more expensive than MTBE per unit of product, to compete favorably with MTBE for the wintertime oxygenate market. (45) However, recent EPA "Tier 2" requirements for summer time reformulated gasoline made it necessary to increase the ethanol content to 13 percent in 1999. Clearly, increasing the ethanol content of gasoline in the near term increases its cost vis-a-vis MTBE-based gasoline.
It is also important to note that ethanol's one-third share of the oxygenate market is concentrated in the Midwest where most of the corn is grown. Many States in the Midwest have sizable ethanol support programs. (46)
The use of MTBE in some parts of the country may have less to do with economics than with the cost of transporting ethanol far from where it is produced. Ethanol is "splash blended" at gasoline distribution tank farms because it cannot be transported via pipeline.
Assessments of repealing the Federal ethanol subsidies differ widely, from no industry (47) to the continuance of the market (about one-third of the current market for ethanol) for the use of ethanol as an oxygenate. Clearly, the continuance of State support for ethanol is a critical issue if the Federal subsidies were to repealed.
Returns to
renewable energy R&D are difficult to calculate, especially, given the
diffuse nature of R&D activity. Research and development is conducted
in a number of countries world wide, and the learning effects cross
borders and cannot always be attributed to a specific R&D activity.
If the goal of R&D is to lower costs, then one measure of effectiveness is to examine the cost of renewable technologies over time. For the Sacramen toMunicipal Utility District (SMUD), which has the largest distributed utility PV system in the world, the PV system average cost (1996 dollars) per watt has fallen from $79 in 1975 to $11.88 in 1990, to $4.90 in 1998 and to $3.65 in 2000. (48), (49) Also, the cost of wind power has declined markedly. The average cost of electricity from wind energy has dropped from 50 cents per kilowatthour in 1980 to a projected 6 cents per kilowatthour in 2000 in favorable wind regimes. (50) Despite these successes in reducing costs, these technologies are still not generally commercially viable.
Another
performance measure of applied R&D "success" is inventions patented.
In order to protect the rights to an invention, a patent is usually
applied for. (51)
A patent has to be obtained within 1 year of publishing the results of the
relevant research in order to gain protection in the United States, and
immediately upon publication to obtain protection abroad. This is
generally insufficient time for market studies, so that more patents are
applied for than are commercially successful. In general, fewer than 10
percent of patents are licensed and, therefore, commercialized. The number
of patents resulting from renewable energy R&D is therefore considered
as a proxy for returns to R&D (Table
8). For the reasons stated above, however, it is a very crude measure
of success of R&D expenditures. In addition, the market success of any
one product (resulting from one patent) can dwarf the successes of
numerous other products, yet be sufficient to spawn a new industry. This
thereby results in large returns to R&D. Finally, there is a widely
varying, unknown time lag between R&D efforts and "successes." Given
these conditions, annual patent counts are, at best, only a very general
indicator of R&D success. It should be noted that the counts include
only patents issued to DOE and the National Renewable Energy Laboratory
(NREL) on inventions reported during each listed fiscal year for contracts
with NREL and its predecessor, the Midwest Research Institute. It does not
include patents retained by DOE contractors.
The effectiveness of tax credits and production incentives has varied considerably, depending on the amounts and certainty of the incentive. The long-term nature and financial support levels of the PURPA Standard Offer 4 contracts in California, in addition to the Federal and State tax credits, provided reasonable assurance that investors in power plants using renewable resources would make a profit. (52) In contrast, the Renewable Energy Production Incentive of EPACT relies upon year-to-year congressional funding, raising the level of uncertainty investors face. It has resulted in only a small amount of additional renewable generating facilities. Other tax credits (e.g., the residential solar/ wind tax credit) have generally had much less impact, simply because the gap between competitive energy prices and energy production costs is greater than the benefit investors perceive such tax credits are worth.
In the case of alcohol fuels, the impact of the Federal 54 cents per gallon incentive was substantial and immediate. Production of fuel ethanol would no doubt drop sharply if the Federal 54 cents per gallon (of ethanol) incentive were removed and States provided no supports for, or, mandates to use, ethanol.
The cost of photovoltaic and wind electricity generation has declined consistently over the past 20 to 25 years. Federal renewable energy R&D, though inconsistently funded, has been undertaken continuously during this time. Although available data are insufficient to establish a quantifiable relationship between R&D funding and renewable energy cost reduction, the data suggest that such benefits have occurred.
Together, the
Federal and State incentives, mandates, and support programs, including
R&D, have been effective when measured by growth in electric
generating capacity and electricity generation, or, in the transportation
sector with growth in ethanol production. However, they failed to ensure
the future self-sustainability of renewable facilities that would
substantially contribute to the overall energy security policy of the era
in which the incentives were created. One reason for this is that although
there have been some reductions in the cost of renewable electric
generating technologies, these cost reductions have not kept pace with the
general declines in cost seen in natural gas-fired generation. These cost
reductions, however, have put renewables in a better competitive position,
especially given the sharp increases in natural gas prices in
2000.
1. A renewable energy source is one that is regenerative or virtually inexhaustible. It includes biomass, geothermal, hydro (water), municipal solid waste, solar photovoltaic, solar thermal, and wind use in the electric utility, or transportation sector.
2. The term "incentive" is used instead of "subsidy." Incentives include subsidies in addition to other Government actions where the Government's financial assistance is indirect. A subsidy is, generally, financial assistance granted by the Government to firms and individuals.
3. The incentives examined in this article refer only to resource-based incentives. Also, this report excludes discussion of local government incentives.
4. "Determining the extent to which Government energy R&D is a subsidy is . . . problematic: often it takes the form of a direct payment to producers or consumers, but the payment is not tied to the production or consumption of energy in the present. If successful, Federal-applied R&D will affect future energy prices and costs, and so could be considered an indirect subsidy." Energy Information Administration, Federal Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect Interventions in Energy Markets , SR/EMEU/92-02 (Washington, DC, November 1992), p. 3. In addition, Government R&D substitutes for private R&D expenditures.
5. An effort to quantify expenditures in non-energy areas is shown in an Office of Management and Budget (OMB) study, Report to Congress on the Costs and Benefits of Federal Regulations (Washington, DC, September 30, 1997). The report estimates the net benefits from Federal health, safety, and environmental regulations at between $30 billion and $3.3 trillion annually, with costs to implement them falling somewhere between $170 billion and $230 billion.
6. Energy Information Administration, Federal Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect Interventions in Energy Markets , SR/EMEU/92-02 (Washington, DC, November 1992).
7. Energy Information Administration, Federal Financial Intervention and Subsidies in Energy Markets 1999: Primary Energy , SR/OIAF/99-03 (Washington, DC, September 1999).
8. Ibid. , Table 5, p. 15. Includes: Renewable Energy Production Incentive, Alternative Fuel Production Credit, Alcohol Fuel Credit, Research and Development for renewable energy, and the Federal Energy Management Program.
9. For an extensive discussion of PURPA, see Energy Information Administration, Changing Structure of the Electric Power Industry: An Update , DOE/EIA-0562 (96) (Washington, DC, December 1996).
10. In 1990, the Solar, Wind, Waste, and Geothermal Incentives Act was passed (Public Law 101-575), giving a window of opportunity for generating plants using these sources to file by Dec. 31, 1994 for QF status with an exemption on the PURPA size limit, lowering the threshold to 50 MW. Construction of the project had to be completed by 1999. The Act was not extended after its effective end date (December 31, 1994), so subsequent to 1994 the 80 megawatt size limit for these energy sources was restored.
11. Avoided cost is the cost to the utility to generate or otherwise purchase electricity from another source.
12. A fifth incentive which is an income tax deduction for alcohol produced from coal and lignite is available. However, currently no alcohol is produced from these sources. Alcohol fuel producers do not qualify for this credit if the source is biomass. Also, there is an income tax deduction for alcohol-fueled vehicles. This article discusses only incentives for renewable resources, so discussion of this deduction is not included.
13. Established by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 (P.L. 101-508), which lowered the 6-cents-per-gallon credit for gasohol established in the Tax Reform Act of 1984 (P.L. 99-198).
14. Originally, the excise tax exemption was part of the National Energy Act of 1978. The excise tax credits and the blenders credit are authorized in the Intermodal Surface Transportation Act's Federal Motor Fuels Excise Tax Credit Provisions. The excise tax credits apply both to "pure" fuel ethanol (e.g., E-85, E-95) and to low-ethanol blends of gasoline (gasoline having as little as 5.7 percent ethanol). The Tax Reform Act of 1984 (P.L. 98-369) subsequently increased the blenders income tax credit to 60 cents per gallon for ethanol, before the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 lowered it to 54 cents. The blenders credit is offset by any excise tax exemptions claimed on the same fuel.
15. The credit is for a maximum of 15 million gallons annually. Eligible producers are those whose annual production is less than 30 million gallons. As with the blender's credit, the small ethanol producer credit is reduced to take into account any excise tax exemption claimed on ethanol output and sales.
16. An alternative formulation is provided in Solar Energy Research Institute, The Potential of Renewable Energy: An Interlaboratory White Paper (SERI/TP-260-3674, March 1990), p. 29.
17. Information on ethanol R&D expenditures is from unpublished budget documents of the U.S. Department of Energy's Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, Office of Transportation Technologies, Office of Fuels Development.
18. Cellulosic feedstocks include agricultural residues from harvesting operations (corn, wheat, rice, etc.), forest wastes/residues (excess growth, dead trees, etc.), and energy crops, i.e., trees and grasses grown specifically for use as energy feedstocks.
19. A renewable portfolio standard (RPS) is a mandate requiring that renewable energy provide a certain percentage of total energy generation or consumption.
20. Net metering refers to an arrangement that permits a facility (using a meter that reads inflows and outflows of electricity) to sell any excess power it generates over its load requirement back to the electrical grid to offset consumption.
21. See http://www.dsireusa.org/, June 27, 2000, and Interstate Renewable Energy Council, North Carolina Solar Center National Summary Report on State Programs and Regulatory Policies for Renewable Energy (Raleigh, NC, January 1998).
22. See, for instance, R.H. Wiser, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, "Evaluating the Impacts of State Renewables Policies on Federal Tax Credit Programs" (Berkeley, California, December 1996).
23. California has more non-hydroelectric renewable generating capability than any other State; see Energy Information Administration, Renewable Energy Annual 1999, DOE/EIA-0603(99) (Washington, DC, March 2000), Table C54.
24. Production incentives do not apply to "emerging technologies."
25. American Wind Energy Association, http://www.awea.org/projects/california.html, September 15, 2000.
26. Sources: See Table 6 of this report, as well as the Renewable Electric Plant Information System (REPiS Database), developed by the National Renewable Energy Laboratory. See http://www.eren.doe.gov/repis, February 15, 2000. These data include facilities which have retired since 1996.
27. In 1981, New York State enacted legislation which established a minimum price of 6 cents per kilowatthour for utility purchases from QFs. As a result, nearly one-third of New York's generation comes from QFs. (See Edison Electric Institute, 1996 Capacity and Generation of Non-Utility Sources of Energy , 30 (1997).)
28. Energy Information Administration, State Energy Price and Expenditures Report 1995, DOE/EIA-0376(95) (Washington, DC, August 1998), p. 50.
29. Science Applications International Corporation, "Assessment of Incentives for Renewable and Alternative Fuels," prepared for the Energy Information Administration (McLean, VA, September 1998).
30. In fact, the result of PURPA and California/Federal financial energy incentive programs of the late 1970s and early 1980s was that the proportion of natural gas-fired nonutility capacity (cogeneration) actually increased between 1980 and 1993, from 55 to 57 percent.
31. Energy Information Administration, "Renewable Electricity Purchases: History and Recent Developments," from Renewable Energy 1998: Issues and Trends, DOE/EIA-0628(98) (Washington, DC, March 1999), Figure 1, p. 2.
32. For a private analysis of PURPA costs, see, Utility Data Institute, Measuring the Competition: Operating Cost Profiles for U.S. Investor-Owned Utilities 1995, 1(1996).
33. Energy Information Administration, Electric Power Monthly, DOE/EIA-0226 (2001/01) (Washington, DC, January 2001), Table 42.
34. Ibid, Figure 2.
35. Refer to Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, FERC Form 1, "Annual Report of Major Electric Utilities, Licensees and Others," Energy Information Administration, Form EIA-412, "Annual Report of Public Electric Utilities," and Rural Utilities Service, RUS Form 7, "Financial and Statistical Report," RUS Form 12a through 12i, "Electric Power Supply Borrowers," and RUS Form 12c through 12g, "Electric Distribution Borrowers with Generating Facilities."
36. The reverse is not true, however. Fifty-five percent (4,474 MWh) of total hydropower purchases in 1995 were from QFs. However, these purchases represented only 10 percent of total 1995 utility power purchases from QFs, so a QF/non-QF comparison is still largely a non-hydro/hydro comparison.
37. California, which accounted for almost 40 percent of U.S. renewable power purchases in 1995, did not use market transaction costs for the first round of PURPA contracts. However, since avoided costs are defined by the States, some States may have done so.
38. The California Energy Commission and the California Public Utilities Commission estimated in 1988 above-market costs of electricity due to Standard Offer 4 (SO4) contracts. While their approach only looked at nonutility facilities with SO4 contracts having prices based on 1983 forecasts of natural gas prices, the study unfortunately does not break out costs associated with renewables. See California Energy Commission/California Public Utilities Commission, "Final Report to the Legislature on: Joint CEC/CPUC Hearings on Excess Electrical Generating Capacity," P150-87-002 (Sacramento, CA, June 1988).
39. Energy Information Administration, Electric Power Monthly, DOE/EIA-0226 (2001/01) (Washington, DC, January 2001), Table 42.
40. For a complete discussion of REPI payments, see website http://www.eren.doe.gov/power/repi.html, December 17, 1999.
41. The ethanol subsidy program began with a provision of the Energy Tax Act of 1978. This provision suspended the Federal excise tax on gasoline blended with alcohol derived from biomass (e.g., corn).
42. Source: 1980-1992, Renewable Fuels Association (see website http://www.ethanolrfa.org/outlook99/99industryoutlook.html); 1993-1999, Energy Information Administration, EIA-819M Monthly Oxygenate Telephone Report (January 2000 and prior issues).
43. Methyl Tertiary Butyl Ether is a fuel oxygenate produced by reacting methanol with isobutylene.
44. This calculation is based on the average prices of gasoline and ethanol between July 1998 and June 1999 and the ethanol subsidy in effect then of 54 cents per gallon of ethanol. See http://www.ncseonline.org/NLE/CRSreports/energy/eng-59.cfm?&CFID=7567020&CFTOKEN=52140940, Table 5.
45. The continued need for octane levels in gasoline initially left the refiner with few choices: increase the aromatic and olefin contents of the fuel, or seek alternative products with favorable blending and performance properties. The increased use of aromatics and olefins meant more severe refinery processes needed to be used, having lower yields per barrel and higher costs for the final gasoline product. Additionally, potential health concerns about these components--from both the direct exposure due to evaporation from the gasoline and the reaction of combustion products contributing to ozone formation--limited the levels at which it was desirable to blend them into fuel. Methanol's use ceased when the Environmental Protection Agency approved MTBE in 1979.
46. Many corn-producing States mandate the use of methanol. In Minnesota, for example, the Omnibus Environment, Natural Resources and Agriculture Appropriations bill (SF 3353) mandated that ethanol plants in the State attain a total annual production level of 240 million gallons per year, enough ethanol to completely satisfy in-State demand. Minnesota will now allocate up to $36.4 million per year for payments to the State's ethanol producers.
47. See GAO Congressional testimony, ress=162.140.64.21&filename=gg97041.txt&directory=/diskb/wais/data/gao, August 4, 2000.
48. Sources: Sacramento Municipal Utility District, Sacramento, CA, 1975-1990: Photovoltaic Validation Study; 1998 and 2000: American Solar Energy Society, Advances in Solar Energy XIV, 2000 , "Sustained Orderly Development and Commercialization of Grid-Connected Photovoltaics: SMUD as a Case Example," Donald E. Osborn, Sacramento Municipal Utility District, February 24, 2000.
49. Because of SMUD's long experience with PV technology and the high volume of their PV purchases and installations, it is likely that their costs are lower than for others.
50. Energy Information Administration, Annual Energy Outlook 2000, DOE/EIA-0383(2000) National Energy Modeling System run AEO2k.d100199A.
51. A patent is a grant by the United States Patent and Trademark Office to the inventor, of the right to exclude others for a period of 17 years from making, using, or selling the invention throughout the country. Thus, the primary reason to apply for a patent is to provide exclusive commercial rights for viable inventions.
52.
Energy Information Administration, Renewable Energy 1998: Issues
and Trends, DOE/EIA-0628(98) (Washington, DC, March 1999), p. 65. See
also, Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory, R. Wiser and E. Kahn, "Alternative
Windpower Ownership Structures: Financing Terms and Project Costs," May
1996, LBNL-38921. According to this study, the most important variable in
comparing wind and natural gas project costs is the relatively low return
on equity (12 percent) that is required by investors in gas projects
compared to 18 percent for wind projects.