Copyright 2001 eMediaMillWorks, Inc.
(f/k/a Federal
Document Clearing House, Inc.)
Federal Document Clearing House
Congressional Testimony
June 19, 2001, Tuesday
SECTION: CAPITOL HILL HEARING TESTIMONY
LENGTH: 1512 words
COMMITTEE:
SENATE ENERGY AND NATURAL RESOURCES
HEADLINE: ELECTRICITY PRICE CAPS, NATIONAL ENERGY PLANS
TESTIMONY-BY: STEVEN M. FETTER, MANAGING DIRECTOR
AFFILIATION: GLOBAL POWER GROUP FITCH, INC.
BODY: June 19, 2001
STATEMENT OF
STEVEN M. FETTER MANAGING DIRECTOR GLOBAL POWER GROUP FITCH, INC. NEW
YORK, NEW YORK
UNITED STATES SENATE COMMITTEE ON ENERGY AND NATURAL
RESOURCES
I appreciate the opportunity to testify before the Committee
on Energy and Natural Resources to offer the views of Fitch on S. 764, a bill to
direct the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission to impose just and reasonable
load-differentiated demand rates or cost-of-service based rates on sales by
public utilities of electric energy at wholesale in the western energy market,
and sections 508-510 of S. 597, the Comprehensive and Balanced Energy Policy Act
of 2001, relating to wholesale electricity rates in the western energy market,
natural gas rates in California, and the sale price of bundled natural gas
transactions. I will speak from the perspective of a member of the financial
community as well as former Chairman of the Michigan Public Service Commission.
By now we are all familiar with the factors that have led to the energy
catastrophe in the Western U.S. electricity market. California's restructuring
plan encouraged utility divestiture of generation and called for a high
proportion of customer demand to be met by spot market supply from day-ahead or
hourly transactions. This exposed the state's three investor-owned utilities,
which were operating under retail price caps, to extreme financial pressures due
to wholesale market volatility. By contrast, in more rational market structures
for electricity and other energy commodities, approximately 85-90% of demand is
normally provided through long-term contracts, with at most only 15% subject to
spot market fluctuations. The extreme volatility of price at the wholesale level
has given rise to urgent calls for a "fix" in the form of lower and lower price
caps.
Three months ago, before this committee, I offered Fitch's views
as to whether price caps could provide a solution to the problems facing
California and the West. While I continue to believe that price caps would
negatively influence the evolution to a competitive electricity market, I am
willing to admit that federal enactment of a uniform price cap at a high level -
such as $
1000 per mwh - might serve a useful purpose. It could
operate as a circuit breaker to cap wholesale prices during the brief periods
when extremely volatile circumstances result in a market that cannot be
contained by any manner of competitive forces. It also probably would not
interfere with any strategic decision making by industry participants since
builders of new generation or transmission would not employ prices at that level
(or higher) in their financing models.
However, to go lower than such a
safety valve type level would undoubtedly slow the nation's movement toward an
efficient competitive wholesale market. We have already seen that imposition of
a low price cap, such as $
250 per mwh or even
$
150 per mwh, can have the negative effect of encouraging
suppliers to seek alternative market outlets or even to slow production, or
could create anomalous pricing patterns during off-peak periods. Continued
tinkering with market rules, especially if at the macro federal level, is sure
to create uncertainty among energy investors and delay implementation of their
business plans - this is even more the case in light of recent ambiguous
economic signs.
A further concern for market participants is that major
investments have been made in California and other states based on the
particular competitive frameworks mandated by state legislatures. Price levels
for generation asset auctions were driven by the new market orientation. A
retrenchment on these policies back to a form of cost-of-service
regulation would likely curb investors' enthusiasm for
additional investment pending clearer signs as to future policy direction. This
is especially true where the change in direction comes from the Congress, which
is considering proposals for price controls that could apply to just California,
or potentially all eleven states within the western energy market, or
conceivably the entire U.S.
What concerns me most about Congressional
involvement in
regulation of the wholesale electricity market
is the uncertainty it engenders among investors. Industry participants,
including federal and state regulators and elected officeholders, have called
for substantial amounts of investment if the nation's utility restructuring
movement is to progress. New generation must be added across the country and
upgrades to the existing transmission grid are needed to transform the former
integrated utility structure into a complement of regional competitive markets
operating in a coordinated manner.
I believe the policies encompassed in
the legislation under consideration today would add to the uncertainty currently
in the minds of investors in light of the serious financial difficulties facing
Pacific Gas & Electric and Southern California Edison. I draw an analogy to
the well-intentioned, but flawed, federal policy enacted within the Public
Utility Regulatory Policies Act, known as PURPA. Passed in 1978, PURPA sought to
encourage both
cogeneration and small power production in order
to diversify electricity supply away from traditional large utility-owned power
plants. In that regard, the law failed miserably. It did succeed, however, in
touching off two decades of regulatory and judicial disputes and creating
billions of dollars in stranded costs - as I saw firsthand as a state utility
regulator.
In 1987, I was appointed to the Michigan Public Service
Commission (MPSC). At the time, I had no idea what PURPA was, but I soon learned
of the positive objectives Congress sought in enacting the legislation.
Unfortunately, those aims only became evident to me from a reading of PURPA,
because its goals were never achieved in its implementation within the State of
Michigan or anywhere else in the U.S.
Soon after the announcement of my
appointment, I began to receive calls - both pro and con -- about the largest
cogeneration facility in the world, a 50% utility-owned
facility, that was to be considered by the MPSC under PURPA. I was confronted
with PURPA issues every day of the six years I served as a state regulator.
Finally, in May 1993, the MPSC resolved the final major
cogeneration matter before the Commission. I left soon after,
never having seen the congressional intent - and good intentions -- underlying
PURPA being manifested.
I offer this example because I firmly believe
that utility
regulation is not an area where the Congress can
step in every few years and attempt to deal with a pressing issue of the moment.
As we saw with PURPA, such a step can have long-term negative economic
consequences. If illegal behavior is occurring within the California market,
laws already exist to remedy those wrongs. But if this body seeks to preempt
state regulatory prerogatives and act as a guardian against market movement in
an upward direction, you will generate growing concern in the minds of investors
and lead them to question whether they really do want to be part of the changing
energy landscape.
Already in California there is talk that the state may
try to back out of some of the agreements it recently negotiated because
wholesale electricity prices have collapsed from the highs of a few months ago.
And what of the contracts that remain in place for the next ten to twenty years?
In view of the proposed about- face on competition under consideration today,
what investor would not fear that five to seven years hence - when the rates
flowing from California's long-term supply contracts far exceed market levels
(just as happened under PURPA) - that today's proponents of price caps would
fight to relieve their constituents from having to pay the "outrageous"
above-market rates being forced upon them. And the situation is not necessarily
confined to the West. The Midwest electricity spike of June 1998 and its
aftermath led Fitch to state that "the electricity market involves unusual risks
that will affect the credit of all market participant" .Indeed, there have been
other instances of rate aberrations in both the electric and natural gas sectors
in various regions of the country over the recent past. Some industry observers
have speculated that the New York City region might experience price or supply
problems this summer.
Does this Congress intend to maintain an ongoing
oversight role so that price controls may be extended beyond the western market
whenever prices in other regions fluctuate upward? If so, the efficiency gains
envisioned coming from a truly competitive energy environment will likely never
be achieved.
Already in the wake of California's serious difficulties,
restructuring activities have come to a dead halt across the country. You may
believe you are playing the role of the cavalry coming over the hill to save the
day, but from where investors sit, it appears more like the waving of a white
flag on electric industry competition.
LOAD-DATE: June 21, 2001