Copyright 2001 eMediaMillWorks, Inc.
(f/k/a Federal
Document Clearing House, Inc.)
Federal Document Clearing House
Congressional Testimony
July 26, 2001, Thursday
SECTION: CAPITOL HILL HEARING TESTIMONY
LENGTH: 3234 words
COMMITTEE:
SENATE ENERGY AND NATURAL RESOURCES
HEADLINE: NATIONAL ENERGY POLICY
TESTIMONY-BY: CURT L. HEBERT, JR., CHAIRMAN,
AFFILIATION: FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
BODY: July 26, 2001
Summary of Testimony of
Curt L. Hebert, Jr.
Chairman, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Before the Committee on Energy and Natural Resources United States
Senate
The guiding principle for restructuring legislation should be to
provide a foundation for the development of a robust wholesale competition in
the electric industry. This would provide electric customers with supply
sufficient to meet their energy needs at the lowest reasonable cost. The
Commission remains committed to developing marketoriented policies that promote
the addition of necessary transmission and generation, and that allow for the
detection and remedying of any anti-competitive behavior.
Legislation
should help ensure that transmission owners and operators have economic
incentives to operate and expand the transmission grid to meet the needs of all
consumers and other market participants. Order No. 2000 encourages the formation
of regional transmission organizations (RTOs). The industry has responded
positively, with innovative efforts to develop efficient and nondiscriminatory
RTOs. because they make economic sense, not because of a legal mandate. We need
to rely on competition instead of traditional regulation wherever possible.
Existing laws that hinder competition, such as PUHCA and
PURPA,
need to be modified or repealed.
The Commission has no direct statutory
authority to promulgate and enforce a set of mandatorv reliability standards.
Possible approaches to reliability include enforcing standards through
identified performance-based measures or through voluntary contracts. Congress
should understand, however, that mandatory reliability rules alone are not
enough to ensure the reliability of the grid.
I believe the Commission
does not need any additional statutory authority under the Federal Power Act to
remedy the problems experienced in California and the West. It is important to
recognize the primary source of the problems: demand kept growing, but supply
did not. The long-term solution to these problems is to have the balancing of
supply and demand done by the marketplace, not the government.
l.
Overview
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:
Good
morning. Thank you for the opportunity to speak today on legislative proposals
relating to restructuring of the electric utility industry.
Our
fundamental electric utility laws were enacted during the Great Depression.
These laws made sense in their time, when competition in the industry, was more
a theory than a reality. These laws were meant to provide a regulatory
substitute for competition. Today. however. these laws often have the ironic
effect of preventing the development of competition. harming the very consumers
they were supposed to protect.
I believe the guiding principle for
restructuring legislation should be to provide a foundation for the development
of a robust wholesale competition in the industry. thereby providing electric
customers with supply sufficient to meet their energy needs at the lowest
reasonable cost. This principle requires different approaches in the
transmission and generation parts of the industry.
Transmission will
have to remain regulated for the foreseeable future. However, transmission must
become a stand-alone business and respond to the market. Legislation should help
ensure that transmission owners and operators have economic incentives to
design, build, operate, and expand the transmission grid to meet the needs of
all consumers and other market participants.
In contrast, in the
wholesale power sector, we need to rely on competition instead of traditional
regulation wherever possible. Existing laws that hinder competition need to be
modified or repealed. While the Commission stands ready to intervene in power
markets when market rules or other factors lead to unjust and
unreasonable prices, legislation reducing the existing barriers to entry will
minimize the need for such efforts in the future.
If.Transmission
Jurisdiction
In 1996, the Commission adopted Order No. 888, requiring
all public utilities to offer nondiscriminatory. open access transmission
service over facilities they own, control or operate. This service has been a
major factor in the growth of wholesale competition in the past few years. Most
wholesale buyers and sellers now have many more trading options than they had in
the past.
In late 1999, the Commission adopted Order No. 2000,
encouraging the formation of regional transmission organizations (RTOs). The
industry generally responded positively, with innovative efforts to develop
large, efficient and nondiscriminatory RTOs. The Commission. too, has worked
hard to give the industry timely and constructive guidance on the development of
RTOs. If properly constituted and truly independent, RTOs can help address and
eliminate remaining obstacles to competition and make the markets more
efficient, for the benefit of electricity consumers in all states. Indeed. RTOs
support wholesale competition and, where states choose to pursue it, retail
competition. But even in the absence of retail competition, consumers will
benefit from increased competition in wholesale markets. For example, RTOs can
be structured to eliminate "pancaking" of transmission rates, better manage
transmission congestion, and facilitate transmission planning across a
multi-state region. There is still a lot of work to do, but I remain confident
that we will reach our RTO goals.
1 see no need for enactment of
legislation allowing FERC to mandate the formation of RTOs. The industry is
already forming RTOs because they make economic sense, not because of a legal
mandate. If RTOs did not make economic sense, then nothing would be gained by
requiring their formation. I am particularly pleased to see that transmission
owners, with the urging of (rather than a directive from) the Commission,
increasingly are reaching the conclusion that a particular type of RTO - a
stand-alone, truly independent transmission company - will best serve the
interests of consumers and the market as a whole.
Some argue that the
Commission's jurisdiction should be expanded to include all transmission by
non-public utilities. However, proposed RTOs in various parts of the country are
making efforts to include the facilities of non-public utilities. If the
industry succeeds in including the facilities of non-public utilities in RTOs,
there may be no need for legislation broadening Commission jurisdiction over
non-public utilities. The priority for Congress now should be to reduce or
remove any legislative barriers to RTO participation by non-public utilities.
1 also do not see a need for legislation requiring FERC to adopt uniform
rules on interconnections. The development and implementation of broad RTOs
will, in turn. promote the development of standardized and non-discriminatory
interconnection procedures. A truly independent RTO has every incentive to
maximize throughput and no incentive to hinder the interconnection of new
generation.
III. Reliability
The recent changes in the electric
power industry have increased the incentive for, and frequency of, violations of
reliability rules adopted by the North American Electric Reliability Council
(NERC). Unfortunately, NERC lacks authority to enforce its rules. As a result,
the issue confronting the industry is whether federal action on reliability is
necessary.
The Commission has no direct statutory authority to
promulgate and enforce a set of mandatory reliability standards. While
reliability issues sometimes fall within the Commission's ratemaking
jurisdiction, the Commission in those cases does not decide whether the
reliability of service is acceptable per se. Rather the Commission decides
whether the rates. terms and conditions of service are just, reasonable and not
unduly discriminatory or preferential from a commercial perspective.
The
lack of federal authority to address reliability issues, and increasing concern
about the shortcomings of the traditional voluntary approach to reliability
issues, have led some in the industry to seek other approaches. One approach to
enhance reliability and promoting customer accountability is to give energy
providers an incentive to provide reliable, efficient service. Conventional
pricing methods do not provide adequate incentives. It is my preference to
afford utilities some type of performance-based measure of accountability to
their customers and their regulators. Consistent with its existing authority,
the Commission could tie earnings and profits to reliability-based and
performance-based criteria.
Another approach that has been pursued is
enforcing reliability standards through contracts. Public utilities may
voluntarily include reliability-related provisions in contracts or tariffs filed
with the Commission because they affect or relate to the rates, terms and
conditions of jurisdictional service. If reliability provisions in Commission
jurisdictional contracts are accepted and on file with the Commission, the
Commission can enforce the reliability-related provisions against public utility
parties to the contracts. A system of such contractual arrangements has been
established by utilities in the Western Systems Coordinating Council (WSCC), the
regional reliability council for the Western United States. The effectiveness of
the WSCC arrangement and the
Commission's ability to enforce it have not
been fully tested. But, a voluntary contractual regime is not the simplest or
most effective means of establishing and adequately enforcing reliability
standards. It depends solely on the willingness of public utilities to make
voluntary filings and, even then, it may not capture the electric facilities of
nonpublic utilities. Reliability is at risk to the extent that not all market
participants are covered by the same requirements.
Another approach to
ensuring reliability is enacting federal legislation. This year, on May 17. the
Administration released its National Energy Policy Report. The Report recommends
that the President direct the Secretary of Energy to work with the
Commission to improve the reliability of the interstate transmission
system and to develop legislation providing for enforcement by a self-regulatory
organization subject to the Commission's oversight.
I believe a
legislative approach may be preferable to the contractual approach discussed
above. I take no position, however, on whether the legislation should be based
on the proposal supported by NERC or any other version of reliability
legislation.
Congress should understand, however, that mandatory
reliability rules alone are not enough to ensure the reliability of the grid. In
its Order No. 2000 on RTOs, the Commission set out at length the need for an RTO
to ensure reliability in each region. In particular. RTOs must have the
authority to ensure the short-term reliability of the regional grid and must be
responsible for planning, and for directing or arranging, necessary transmission
expansion and upgrades that will enable it to provide efficient and reliable
transmission service.
As discussed below, we also need to find ways to
encourage and facilitate the construction of new transmission facilities. And,
of course, we must have adequate generating resources. The Commission is
continually reassessing its existing regulations and policies to promote market
entry and the removal of regulatory barriers to enhanced competition in the
wholesale supply and interstate delivery of energy products and services. For
example, on March 14, 2001 and May 16, 2001, the Commission issued orders
removing regulatory obstacles and providing incentives to increased energy
supply and reduced demand in California and the rest of the West.
IV.Power Sales Rates and Market Power
While not the focal point
of today's hearing, the problems recently in the electricity markets in
California and the Western United States are an inescapable background to some
of the legislative proposals now being considered. Those problems have led many
to argue that the Commission needs additional statutory authority or obligations
to ensure that wholesale prices remain just and reasonable.
I disagree.
Since I became Chairman in January of this year, the Commission has used its
existing authority firmly and effectively to mitigate prices in Western markets.
The Commission has issued dozens of orders this year involving wholesale markets
in California and the West. As a result of those orders and other factors,
prices in those markets are continuing to decline substantially.
The
problems in California were not caused by any inadequacies in the Federal Power
Act regarding rates and market power, and preventing such problems in the future
is not dependent on adding to the Commission's authority or obligations.
Instead, such arguments merely distract us from the primary source of the
problems: demand kept 0rowing, but supply did not.
The long-term
solution to these problems is to have the balancing of supply and demand done by
the marketplace, not the government. While the Commission has acknowledged and
addressed the need for short-term, market-oriented price mitigation in
California and the West, these measures must not become permanent crutches. We
must find market-driven ways to promote new sources of supply and transmission,
and encourage appropriate conservation by consumers. Price mitigation should
continue no longer than absolutely necessary, and should be replaced as soon as
possible by full reliance on market-based outcomes.
V.Regional
Transmission Planning and Siting
Since the Commission adopted its open
access requirements in 1996, the use of the interstate transmission grid has
grown dramatically. Also, wholesale markets have become much more regional than
local, encompassing large inulti-state areas. Unfortunately, however, the grid
has not been expanded commensurately. Thus, the grid increasingly is pushed to
its operational limits, and transmission constraints frequently prevent the most
efficient use of generation facilities. The institutional structures for
planning and expanding the grid are not meeting our needs.
In planning
grid expansions, we need to move toward a more regional approach. I believe RTOs
can fulfill this role. By definition, RTOs will encompass large trading areas.
An RTO-based planning process will allow all market participants within these
areas to express their needs and concerns. Since RTOs must be independent of
market participants, all participants will be assured of a nondiscriminatory
planning process. RTOs that are based on the model of a stand-alone, for-profit
transmission company will be particularly motivated to expand the grid when
appropriate to maximize transmission throughput, and thus, transmission revenue.
The authorization and siting of grid expansions has generally been
performed under state law. While some argue that state authorities are too
parochial to perform this responsibility well in today's regional, multi-state
markets, I am not so persuaded.
However, a federal backstop role may be
appropriate in certain circumstances. For example, Congress could reasonably
decide to establish a federal siting process, subject to certain limitations, if
an RTO is unable to obtain siting authorization from a State within a specified
time.
Vl.Market Transparency Rules
In the past, utilities had
little or no reason to keep their costs and transactions confidential. Utility
prices were fully regulated on a cost-plus model, and competition was generally
insubstantial. In today's competitive markets, however, confidentiality of price
and customer information can be critical to a utility's success.
The
Commission has seen increasing struggles among industry participants on how to
reconcile the need for confidential information in competitive markets with a
statutory and regulatory framework premised on full disclosure of cost and price
information. It is not vet clear to me how best to reconcile these tensions. One
approach the Commission has used is to require disclosure of bids in centralized
trading markets, but only after a lag of several months. Other approaches may be
feasible, too, so long as they reasonably balance the needs of competitors to
preserve commercially-sensitive information with the needs of regulators and the
public for information to ensure that jurisdictional rates remain just,
reasonable and not unduly discriminatory or preferential.
VII.Other
Provisions A. PUHCA
The Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA)
requires registered holding companies to submit to extensive regulation by the
Securities and Exchange Commission. PUHCA also generally requires holding
companies to operate an "integrated" and contiguous system. As a result, PUHCA
encourages concentrations of generation ownership and control in local markets
that are inconsistent with competition and discourages asset combinations that
could be pro-competitive. PUHCA may also provide a significant disincentive for
investment in independent transmission companies that would qualify as RTOs.
Under PUHCA, any entity that owns or controls facilities used for the
transmission of electric energy - such as an RTO - falls within the definition
of a public utility company, and any owner of ten percent or more of such a
company would be a holding company and potentially could be required to become a
registered holding company. This could serve as a significant disincentive for
investments in independent transmission companies that qualify as RTOs.
PUHCA was enacted primarily to undo harms caused by byzantine holding
company structures that no longer exist. In the decades since PUHCA was enacted,
utility regulation has increased substantially, under the Federal Power Act,
federal securities laws and state laws. PUHCA has outlived its usefulness. and
now does more harm than good. PUHCA should be repealed.
B.
PURPA The Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act
(
PURPA) was enacted in the late-1970s, in the aftermath of that
decade's energy crises. The legislation's goal was to remove impediments to the
use of cogeneration and renewable-based generation, and promote their use by
allowing such generators to require utilities to buy their power at the
utilities' avoided costs.
Today, the impediments addressed in
PURPA are gone (although other impediments may exist, such as
the need for grid expansion). Also,
PURPA's "forced sale"
requirements are no longer necessary, in light of the availability of open
access transmission, to promote the development of competition, and more often
serve to distort competitive outcomes. Congress should repeal
PURPA, while "grandfather] ng" existing
PURPA
contracts.
Vlll. Conclusion
We need less, not more, regulation
in the generation business. However, we will continue to regulate transmission
for the foreseeable future, while encouraging transmission to become a
stand-alone business and respond to the market. Congress must focus on removing
impediments to the competitive restructuring that is taking place. Outdated
laws, such as PUHCA and
PURPA, are hindering effective
restructuring. The best way for Congress to help electricity consumers is to
promote wholesale competition through the legislative changes described above.
LOAD-DATE: July 31, 2001